08.12.2012 Views

62) decentralised governance of irrigation water in cambodia - CDRI

62) decentralised governance of irrigation water in cambodia - CDRI

62) decentralised governance of irrigation water in cambodia - CDRI

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

that Cambodians have practised large-scale <strong>irrigation</strong> agriculture for over a millennium, most<br />

famously dur<strong>in</strong>g the Angkor era (see, for example, Moore 1989). Dat<strong>in</strong>g back to the 11 th century,<br />

the eight by two kilometre West Baray reservoir is an example <strong>of</strong> Angkor-era <strong>in</strong>frastructure<br />

which is still <strong>in</strong> use today. Overall, while Cambodia’s history <strong>of</strong> <strong>water</strong> management may not<br />

be as l<strong>in</strong>ear, uniform or well-documented as Bali’s, it still provides an important backdrop for<br />

modern <strong>irrigation</strong> <strong>governance</strong>.<br />

2.4 Water Scarcity and the Irrigation Service Fee<br />

Compared across different contexts, what does “pay<strong>in</strong>g for <strong>water</strong>” really mean?<br />

In developed and develop<strong>in</strong>g countries alike, most 21 st century farmers can now expect to<br />

pay a fee <strong>in</strong> return for access to <strong>irrigation</strong> systems. Even where upfront <strong>in</strong>frastructure costs are<br />

covered by the state, ongo<strong>in</strong>g operation and ma<strong>in</strong>tenance (O&M) costs are <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>gly be<strong>in</strong>g<br />

shifted on to local communities and outsourced to private contractors (Molle et al.: Wester<br />

2009: 341-342). This transition has occurred <strong>in</strong> the context <strong>of</strong> two (probably related) trends:<br />

the neoliberal era contraction <strong>of</strong> central government budgets, and the Agenda 21 promotion <strong>of</strong><br />

decentralisation and “subsidiarity”.<br />

In Australia and the United States, <strong>water</strong> has come to be regarded as a scarce resource<br />

with a dist<strong>in</strong>ct economic value and farmers must pay a market-based price for their <strong>water</strong><br />

allocations and entitlements. In contrast, <strong>water</strong> is rarely seen as physically scarce <strong>in</strong> Cambodia.<br />

However, the economic significance <strong>of</strong> <strong>water</strong> is a serious consideration. The new PIMD policy<br />

has <strong>in</strong>troduced a new rule for Cambodian farmers to pay an Irrigation Service Fee (ISF) to<br />

their local FWUC committee. The ISF <strong>in</strong> Cambodia and the <strong>water</strong> fees <strong>in</strong> Australia are based<br />

on very different economic premises. On the one hand, Australia’s Murray Darl<strong>in</strong>g Bas<strong>in</strong> is<br />

<strong>in</strong>frastructure-rich yet <strong>water</strong>-poor; it suffers from what Molden (2007) would term a “physical<br />

scarcity” <strong>of</strong> <strong>water</strong>. To manage this scarcity, the <strong>water</strong> is rationed by price: the region’s farmers<br />

must pay a fee for the <strong>water</strong> itself (i.e. per megalitre). In comparison, Cambodia’s ISF is<br />

designed to address the very different problem <strong>of</strong> “economic scarcity”. Cambodia is relatively<br />

<strong>water</strong>-rich, yet is <strong>in</strong>frastructure-poor; despite the abundance <strong>of</strong> <strong>water</strong>, Cambodian farmers do<br />

not have the means to exploit it productively. Accord<strong>in</strong>gly, the ISF goes to the improvement<br />

and ma<strong>in</strong>tenance <strong>of</strong> <strong>water</strong> <strong>in</strong>frastructure and supports the operation costs <strong>of</strong> the FWUCs. It<br />

does not relate to the amount <strong>of</strong> <strong>water</strong> actually used.<br />

The dist<strong>in</strong>ction between “economic” and “physical” scarcity is based on sound economic<br />

logic and is well accepted <strong>in</strong> academic and policy-mak<strong>in</strong>g spheres. However, when applied to<br />

complex local situations, it is a dist<strong>in</strong>ction that is apt to become blurred. There are a number<br />

<strong>of</strong> possible reasons for this. First, due to lapses <strong>in</strong> communication, local people may not<br />

understand the purpose <strong>of</strong> user fees. For example, given that the “ISF” is commonly translated<br />

<strong>in</strong>to Khmer as “<strong>water</strong> fee” rather than “<strong>in</strong>frastructure fee”, do Cambodian farmers actually<br />

know what they are pay<strong>in</strong>g for? And how does this perception <strong>in</strong>fluence their will<strong>in</strong>gness to<br />

pay? Second, a generalised label <strong>of</strong> “economic scarcity” at the river bas<strong>in</strong> scale can mask<br />

acute physical scarcity at the village and plot scales. In Cambodia, this might occur when an<br />

upstream farmer blocks an <strong>irrigation</strong> canal and thus prevents <strong>water</strong> from reach<strong>in</strong>g the farm<strong>in</strong>g<br />

plots located further downstream. Furthermore, physical scarcity <strong>in</strong> the dry season is a grow<strong>in</strong>g<br />

issue with <strong>in</strong>creased double-cropp<strong>in</strong>g <strong>of</strong>ten rely<strong>in</strong>g on schemes orig<strong>in</strong>ally designed and built<br />

for wet season supplementary <strong>irrigation</strong> only.<br />

<strong>CDRI</strong> Work<strong>in</strong>g Paper Series No. <strong>62</strong><br />

7

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!