25.10.2017 Views

BusinessDay 25 Oct 2017

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

Wednesday <strong>25</strong> <strong>Oct</strong>ober <strong>2017</strong><br />

FT FINANCIAL TIMES<br />

C002D5556<br />

BUSINESS DAY<br />

A3<br />

Prepare for Nafta, the<br />

zombie edition<br />

World Business Newspaper<br />

Victory for Macron<br />

as EU ministers<br />

back curbs on<br />

migrant labour<br />

Tighter laws on ‘posting’ of foreign workers<br />

risks east-west split across bloc<br />

MEHREEN KHAN AND<br />

ANNE-SYLVAINE CHASSANY<br />

Emmanuel Macron, the French<br />

president, has won a significant<br />

victory in his efforts at European<br />

reform after EU ministers<br />

voted to back a Paris-led<br />

campaign to tighten restrictions on the<br />

so-called “posting” of foreign workers.<br />

Following lengthy talks in Luxembourg,<br />

EU ministers agreed the practice,<br />

which allows employers to temporarily<br />

“post” migrant workers to another<br />

member state without the need to<br />

abide by the local labour rules, would<br />

be limited to 12 months with an option<br />

to extend for a further six.<br />

However, Mr Macron’s victory could<br />

come at a price by further damaging<br />

Europe’s already strained east-west relations.<br />

Several eastern nations, including<br />

Hungary and Poland, voted against<br />

the reform, while the Czech Republic’s<br />

labour minister warned limits on the<br />

free movement of workers risks stoking<br />

anti-EU sentiment in her country.<br />

In his five months in office Mr<br />

Macron has railed against posting as<br />

encouraging “social dumping” from<br />

low-wage to high-wage countries and<br />

vowed to protect European workers<br />

from the vagaries of unscrupulous employers.<br />

“Europe is moving forward,” the<br />

French president tweeted on Tuesday<br />

as he welcomed the deal. “More protections,<br />

fewer frauds. Perseverance,<br />

dialogue and ambition enables Europe<br />

to transform for the benefit of all.”<br />

His campaign for employee protections<br />

is in part designed to neuter<br />

France’s Eurosceptic far-right and farleft,<br />

which have made election gains<br />

by portraying the EU as being against<br />

workers’ rights.<br />

But it has stoked significant resentment<br />

in Europe’s eastern capitals where<br />

it is viewed as an assault on the freedom<br />

of their workers and companies to operate<br />

in the single market.<br />

Poland, the biggest exporter of<br />

• Wang Qishan ineligible for another<br />

five-year term on Central<br />

Committee<br />

Wang Qishan, the feared<br />

head of Chinese president<br />

Xi Jinping’s anti-corruption<br />

campaign, was not named to<br />

posted workers in the EU, has dubbed<br />

Mr Macron’s obsession with posted<br />

workers “arrogant” and “lacking political<br />

experience”. Michaela Marksova, the<br />

Czech labour minister, warned ahead<br />

of the negotiations that the issue could<br />

take the country “far closer to Czechxit”,<br />

or exit from the EU.<br />

The fraught negotiations in Luxembourg,<br />

which ran late into Monday<br />

evening, were complicated by France’s<br />

insistence on a 12-month cap, say EU<br />

diplomats. An original reform from the<br />

European Commission set two-year<br />

limits and had broad agreement from<br />

the newer member states.<br />

In an eventual compromise, some<br />

eastern countries backed by Portugal<br />

and Spain insisted that truck drivers<br />

should be exempted from the tightened<br />

rules. But the concessions were not<br />

enough for Poland, Hungary, Latvia and<br />

Lithuania to back the deal, which passed<br />

with a qualified majority vote. The UK<br />

and Ireland abstained.<br />

Nicolai von Ondarza, deputy head<br />

of Europe research at SWP, the German<br />

think-tank, said this was a rare example<br />

of larger EU governments choosing to<br />

outvote smaller member states rather<br />

than go back to the negotiating table.<br />

Another instance was a controversial<br />

EU deal in 2015 to relocate refugees —<br />

a decision that sparked revolt in the<br />

eastern bloc and which has been legally<br />

challenged by Budapest and Prague at<br />

the European Court of Justice.<br />

Mr von Ondarza warned that abandoning<br />

consensus in divisive areas such<br />

as free movement would stoke the grievances<br />

of central and eastern European<br />

governments against Brussels. “There is<br />

a danger the majority will overplay their<br />

hand,” he said.<br />

The posted workers agreement,<br />

which will now be debated by the European<br />

Parliament, also split the unity<br />

of the four Visegrad nations: Poland,<br />

Hungary, Slovakia and the Czech Republic.<br />

The Slovaks backed a deal, as did<br />

the Czechs eventually.<br />

China anti-graft tsar cut from<br />

top Communist party leadership<br />

TOM MITCHELL<br />

Page A4<br />

the Communist party’s new Central<br />

Committee on Tuesday, making<br />

him ineligible for another five-year<br />

term on the party’s most powerful<br />

body.<br />

Mr Wang’s possible re-appointment<br />

to the Politburo Standing<br />

Committee had been one of the<br />

most hotly discussed outcomes at<br />

Continues on page A4<br />

Trump team’s tax cut defence is outlandish and incoherent<br />

The corporate levy is not what stops companies from investing<br />

MARTIN SANDBU<br />

Free Lunch had already expressed<br />

doubts about the<br />

claim by Donald Trump’s<br />

administration that its planned<br />

corporate tax cuts will mostly benefit<br />

US workers. But now Kevin Hassett,<br />

chairman of Trump’s Council of<br />

Economic Advisers, has doubled<br />

down on the claim by presenting<br />

calculations purporting to show<br />

that cutting the corporate tax rate<br />

to 20 per cent would boost average<br />

household income by $4,000<br />

to $9,000 and median household<br />

income by $3,000 to $7,000. To be<br />

clear, the claim is that much of that<br />

extra income is to come from higher<br />

wages, not higher dividends.<br />

The argument is bizarre in so<br />

many ways. The numbers are far<br />

too large to pass any smell test.<br />

Hassett confusingly (or confusedly)<br />

attributes the decades-long divorce<br />

of median wages from productivity<br />

growth and profits to the US’s relatively<br />

high corporate taxes — even<br />

though that divergence is largely<br />

driven by increasing inequality within<br />

wages (which means the average<br />

has grown faster than the median).<br />

He partly relies on a simplistic<br />

empirical argument that low-tax<br />

OECD countries have seen faster<br />

wage growth in recent years than<br />

high-tax ones. But there are plenty<br />

of other reasons for that, in particular,<br />

these low-tax countries are<br />

predominantly eastern European<br />

ones that both got out of their crises<br />

quickly and had much lower<br />

wages to begin with so they should<br />

be growing faster. Finally, in his remarks<br />

introducing the study, Hassett<br />

mixes up the respectable claim that<br />

lower corporate taxes could encourage<br />

investment in productive capital<br />

with the fallacy that repatriating<br />

Virgin Money boss<br />

warns sexism is still rife<br />

in the City of London<br />

Page A5<br />

Donald Trump speaks during a meeting with chief executives of manufatcturing companies at the White House in February © EPA<br />

corporate income earned abroad<br />

would do so. Yesterday we refuted<br />

the idea that corporate profits are<br />

trapped offshore.<br />

The reactions from professional<br />

economists have been intense.<br />

Lawrence Summers has attacked<br />

Hassett, wrapping his substantive<br />

critique in unusually harsh personal<br />

criticism. The CEA’s numbers, he<br />

points out, imply that total wages<br />

would riseby 300-450 per cent of<br />

the size of the tax cuts. He has since<br />

repeated the criticism, emphasising<br />

in particular that when companies<br />

can fully expense new capital investment,<br />

the corporate tax rate has little<br />

effect on the incentive to invest in<br />

capital financed by equity.<br />

Meanwhile Jason Furman, Hassett’s<br />

immediate predecessor at the<br />

CEA, identifies more gaps in the<br />

“wild” reasoning. He points out<br />

that “the White House methodology<br />

yields the absurd conclusion<br />

that eliminating the corporate tax<br />

altogether would boost annual<br />

household wages by up to $20,000”.<br />

There have been interesting<br />

responses from right-leaning economists.<br />

Harvard’s Greg Mankiw, an<br />

earlier CEA predecessor, has posted<br />

the maths of a stylised example of<br />

corporate tax cuts, which he shows<br />

can in theory easily increase wages<br />

by more than the size of the tax<br />

cut. John Cochrane has elaborated<br />

on the algebra and why it matters;<br />

Steven Landsburg offers a very<br />

useful graphical illustration of the<br />

argument, and also explains it in<br />

plain words.<br />

It is important to be clear about<br />

the main point here: that a corporate<br />

tax cut can increase wages is a standard<br />

result that most economists<br />

across the political spectrum would<br />

agree with. As Michael Strain puts<br />

it: “That’s not just a political talk-<br />

ing point; it’s the consensus view<br />

of professional economists.” It is<br />

equally important to understand the<br />

mechanism underlying the model:<br />

it is that companies will respond to<br />

the lower tax rate by investing more<br />

in productive capital, and it is this<br />

increase in the capital stock that<br />

raises wages.<br />

But, Strain rightly adds, don’t<br />

exaggerate. For anyone who thinks<br />

Mankiw’s algebra lends credence to<br />

the CEA’s quantitative claims, other<br />

economists show why this is not so.<br />

First, according to Brad DeLong, a<br />

mistake in the algebra means the effect<br />

is overstated. Second, the model<br />

assumes that the US is a small open<br />

economy when in reality it is neither<br />

small nor very open (for its size),<br />

which means there is not unlimited<br />

investment that could come in from<br />

abroad. Third, the model ignores the<br />

funding of the tax cut — increased<br />

borrowing, spending cuts or other<br />

tax rises — which could diminish<br />

the incentive to invest.<br />

And finally Paul Krugman very<br />

usefully takes on Landsburg’s geometry<br />

to explain in easy terms what<br />

the graphicalanalysis misses. Above<br />

all, this is (to reinforce the point) that<br />

the proposed mechanism by which<br />

corporate tax cuts raise wages is by<br />

increasing the capital stock. But that<br />

takes time, Krugman points out, and<br />

in the meantime asset prices will rise<br />

first (benefiting the asset rich). And<br />

if the increased investment does<br />

happen, the model assumes it does<br />

so by increasing capital imports — in<br />

other words, through a larger trade<br />

deficit; much larger given the assumed<br />

investment response. If there<br />

is anything the Trump administration<br />

claims not to want, this is it.<br />

So the administration’s defence<br />

of corporate tax cuts is both outlandish<br />

and incoherent.

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!