20.03.2013 Views

Valuation Techniques for Social Cost-Benefit Analysis: - HM Treasury

Valuation Techniques for Social Cost-Benefit Analysis: - HM Treasury

Valuation Techniques for Social Cost-Benefit Analysis: - HM Treasury

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

As a minimum value estimates should be fully explained to acknowledge the utility derived from<br />

the consumption of complementary goods. A preferred approach (if possible) would be to<br />

control <strong>for</strong> the consumption of complementary goods or to subtract the market price of the<br />

complementary goods from the overall value estimate.<br />

8. Time-invariant factors such as personality traits should be controlled<br />

<strong>for</strong> (panel data estimation only).<br />

In practice, the life satisfaction regression is estimated assuming the existence of time-invariant<br />

unobserved determinants ( i ) of well-being. The life satisfaction variable is ordinal in nature but<br />

Ferrer-i-Carbonell and Frijters (2004) show that assuming cardinality as opposed to ordinality in<br />

the LS function makes no difference to estimation results. For ease of estimation and exposition,<br />

the preferred model has there<strong>for</strong>e become an OLS regression with fixed effects to control <strong>for</strong> i :<br />

LSit M it Qit<br />

X<br />

(24)<br />

1 2 3 it i it<br />

Fixed effects models work by using the longitudinal nature of the data to control <strong>for</strong><br />

determinants of life satisfaction which do not change over time ( i ). This might include<br />

characteristics such as extroversion and introversion which are strongly associated with wellbeing<br />

or factors such as an innate tendency / ability to be happy or satisfied. Because these<br />

factors do not change over time they can be controlled <strong>for</strong> using a separate intercept <strong>for</strong> every<br />

individual in a fixed effects model.<br />

Random effects models can also control <strong>for</strong> i but it makes the assumption that the individual<br />

effect i is uncorrelated with the other regressors in the model ( X ).This assumption is not<br />

it<br />

likely to hold in the life satisfaction function as we would expect factors such as extroversion to<br />

be strongly correlated with some of the covariates included in the model.<br />

9. Adaptation effects<br />

Evidence suggests that many people adapt quickly to many positive and negative life events,<br />

including marriage, divorce, disability, pay rises and unemployment (Brickman et al. ; Larsen and<br />

Prizmic, 2008 (Eid and Larsen eds); Frijters et al, 2008). Adaptation effects can be estimated<br />

using panel data and by including time-lagged explanatory variables <strong>for</strong> the good being valued.<br />

For example, the life satisfaction of individual i in period t could be written as:<br />

LSit 1 Mit<br />

2Qit<br />

3Qit<br />

1 4X<br />

it i it<br />

(25)<br />

The time-path effect of the non-market good (Q) is captured by parameters 2 and 3 . Here,<br />

the good (Q) occurred or was consumed in the previous period (t-1) and so Qt picks up any<br />

adaptation effects. If there is adaptation to Q, then<br />

5 . Of course, specifications can be<br />

adopted with further lags into past periods. The value of the good should be estimated <strong>for</strong> the<br />

good‘s entire time-path as follows:<br />

2 3<br />

WTP ( years : t 1 t)<br />

(26)<br />

5 If there is adaptation to a non-market ‗bad‘ then<br />

1<br />

2<br />

.<br />

3<br />

2<br />

3<br />

45

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!