20.03.2013 Views

Valuation Techniques for Social Cost-Benefit Analysis: - HM Treasury

Valuation Techniques for Social Cost-Benefit Analysis: - HM Treasury

Valuation Techniques for Social Cost-Benefit Analysis: - HM Treasury

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

58<br />

Regardless of the elicitation <strong>for</strong>mat adopted, respondents should always be reminded of their<br />

budget constraint (Bateman et al, 2002, p.143). This is to help ensure that respondents perceive<br />

the questions as real economic choices.<br />

The Design of Choice Modelling Questionnaires<br />

Choice modelling questionnaires are typically structured in much the same way as contingent<br />

valuation questionnaires (see, <strong>for</strong> example, Tuan and Navrud, 2006). The difference between the<br />

two methods is that choice modelling focuses on the attributes of a non-market good (and the<br />

valuation of these attributes) instead of the whole good. By valuing attributes, choice modelling<br />

can also value the good as a whole.<br />

Most non-market goods can be described by their attributes and the levels that these attributes<br />

take. For example, Mourato et al (2005) estimate the value of different schemes to reduce the<br />

amount of sewage overflows that end up in the River Themes. Such schemes or ‗goods‘ can be<br />

described more specifically in terms of their underlying attributes. In this study, these attributes<br />

include how much the sewage reducing proposal costs (COST), the reduction in fish deaths it<br />

causes (FISH), the reduction in number of days when exposure to river quality is a health risk<br />

(HEALTH), and the reduction in visual disamenity it causes (SEWAGE). Similarly, a wetland can be<br />

described by its bird population, water quality, diversity of animal life, etc. There<strong>for</strong>e the value<br />

that individuals attach to the wetland‘s existence is determined by the values attached to the<br />

elements that describe it as a whole.<br />

All CM methods:<br />

present respondents with alternative descriptions of a good, differentiated by different<br />

levels of its attributes; then<br />

ask respondents to either rank, rate, or chose.<br />

For the latter task there are four main choice modelling methods 2 :<br />

choice experiments (‗chose‘);<br />

contingent ranking (‗rank‘);<br />

contingent rating (‗rate‘); and<br />

paired comparisons (‗chose then rate‘).<br />

Choice experiments present respondents with a series of choices between the status quo or ‗do<br />

nothing‘ option and an alternative option or options. The ‗do nothing‘ option in Mourato et al<br />

(2005) is to pay nothing annually and to bear the expected annual negative side effects (FISH,<br />

HEALTH, and SEWAGE) if no actions are taken to counter the sewage overflows. The alternative<br />

options refer to alternative descriptions of the good in question. One option may be costly but<br />

results in a large reduction in the negative sewage side effects; another may be cheap but result<br />

in a modest reduction in the negative sewage side effects.<br />

The contingent ranking approach asks respondents to rank the ‗do nothing‘ and alternative<br />

options from most to least preferred.<br />

The contingent rating approach presents respondents with a series of single alternative<br />

descriptions of the good. The respondent then has to rate the strength of their preference <strong>for</strong><br />

each description on a semantic or numeric scale.<br />

2 (Hanley, 2001).

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!