30.06.2013 Views

The South Africa – Viet Nam Rhino Horn Trade Nexus (PDF ... - WWF

The South Africa – Viet Nam Rhino Horn Trade Nexus (PDF ... - WWF

The South Africa – Viet Nam Rhino Horn Trade Nexus (PDF ... - WWF

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

situation at the source: south africa<br />

rhino ownership by both private and State stakeholders, which could support the ongoing growth in<br />

rhino numbers and range in <strong>South</strong> <strong>Africa</strong>. Some hold the view that recent indications of declining live<br />

rhino sale prices and an increasing number of private owners divesting themselves of rhinos may continue<br />

without legalization of horn trade, thus reducing the land available for rhinos and negatively impacting<br />

upon rhino numbers in the long term. Whilst this is not yet an established trend, a reduction in<br />

potential rhino range, as well as financial resources available to support rhino conservation, have been<br />

identified as conservation challenges that exist above and beyond the current poaching crisis. Some proponents<br />

also argue that if legalizing the trade is found to not work, producing unacceptable consequences<br />

and outcomes, they would be accepting of interventions to shut the trade down completely.<br />

It should be recognized that many proponents of legal trade are deeply concerned about the future of<br />

<strong>South</strong> <strong>Africa</strong>’s rhinos and believe, as a matter of urgency, that trade may prove a compelling solution to<br />

the present crisis. At the same time, however, there is no unified viewpoint amongst legal trade proponents<br />

concerning the higher-level objectives of a legal trade, and there is a clear gap between those<br />

who are motivated to use trade to curtail rhino poaching and those wishing to use trade to generate<br />

maximum revenue.<br />

In fact, the salient features of how a legal trade would be structured and which countries or markets<br />

would be part of the trade remain completely vague and any discussion of the issue is bedevilled by the<br />

fact that the “devil is in the detail”. For example, those in favour of legal trade argue that DNA analyses<br />

could be used to distinguish between legal and illegal horn at different stages in the market, but no<br />

details of exactly how this would be mechanistically undertaken, who would pay for it or how it would<br />

be enforced, have been set out to date. Another example concerns the range of different market mechanisms<br />

that have been proposed to manage a legal trade, but there is no consensus on how prices should<br />

be set or the best process for controlling the market. Some propose adopting a central selling organization<br />

approach like DeBeers did with its diamond cartel, others have mentioned an auction-type scenario<br />

that would allow rhino horn to sell at market values, whilst still others have advocated a central registration<br />

in <strong>South</strong> <strong>Africa</strong> for legally-obtained horns, which would be shipped to the government of the<br />

agreed trading partner; that government would then decide who could purchase the horns locally.<br />

Similarly, there is the issue of rhino horn that could potentially supply the trade coming from a number<br />

of different sources within both the State and private sectors. Whilst existing rhino horn stockpiles,<br />

ongoing natural mortalities or active dehorning operations could all supply horn, it is not always exactly<br />

clear which sources are being referred to in discussions around legal trade in rhino horn. Limited<br />

work has also been done in quantifying how much horn could be made available from <strong>South</strong> <strong>Africa</strong><br />

from different sources under different trade scenarios, but this could have a significant impact on the<br />

efficacy of using a legal supply to mitigate poaching impacts. <strong>The</strong>se kinds of unresolved issues serve to<br />

confound the discussion.<br />

Arguments given against legal trade in rhino horn<br />

Opponents of legal trade in rhino horn also accept that a recharged demand for rhino horn currently<br />

exists in Asia, but remain opposed to legal trade at the present time for a variety of reasons. Like those<br />

on the other side of the fence, a diversity of opinions is found, ranging from dogmatic or philosophical<br />

opposition on principle to more pragmatic considerations of timing or other detail. On one side of the<br />

spectrum are those commentators who believe that any form of trade or sustainable utilization of wildlife<br />

is inherently wrong and should never be countenanced. However, such views are contrary to the<br />

sustainable-use philosophies that form the cornerstone of conservation approaches adopted by the<br />

majority of <strong>Africa</strong>n rhino range States and many other conservation bodies. Indeed, the practical application<br />

of sustainable-use principles has been one of the reasons for <strong>South</strong> <strong>Africa</strong>’s White <strong>Rhino</strong> conservation<br />

success story, the current poaching crisis notwithstanding.<br />

It is an established fact that demand for rhino horn has been dramatically reduced in many former<br />

major markets in the past and some observers believe that this may be possible to achieve again in new<br />

markets such as <strong>Viet</strong> <strong>Nam</strong>. For example, Japan, <strong>South</strong> Korea, Taiwan and Yemen all were once major<br />

consumers of rhino horn, but no longer feature in the present rhino horn trade in a significant way.<br />

Even mainland China falls into this category to some extent as entire avenues of trade, for example the<br />

use of rhino horn in manufactured traditional medicines, is no longer occurring. It is further argued<br />

that awareness campaigns, coupled with unequivocal expressions of political will and government<br />

actions to curtail illegal trade, may have the potential to significantly reduce current rhino horn usage,<br />

particularly in the non-traditional market that <strong>Viet</strong> <strong>Nam</strong> represents. <strong>The</strong> effectiveness of such efforts,<br />

however, could be compromised by legalizing the supply of rhino horn, some argue.<br />

A key issue to consider is the fact that all of the former rhino horn-consuming countries/territories in<br />

Asia, and also <strong>Viet</strong> <strong>Nam</strong>, have effected legal bans against the trade and most have moved to completely<br />

remove rhino horn as an approved ingredient in their traditional medicine pharmacopoeias. Any proposal<br />

to CITES to allow legal trade in rhino horn would require the identification of a trading partner<br />

in the form of a consumer interested in opening a legal rhino horn market, but there has been no clear<br />

indication of interest from any of the known end-user countries/territories in Asia to date.<br />

Furthermore, as domestic sales of rhino horn are illegal in virtually all consumer countries/territories<br />

that might be a trading partner, any move to lift internal trade bans would require necessary changes<br />

to national legislation to permit legal trade. And finally, if <strong>Viet</strong> <strong>Nam</strong> is targeted as the trading partner<br />

owing to the role it currently plays as the world’s primary rhino horn consumer, many remain wary<br />

whether the country would be able to implement a structured legal trade regime and adequately police<br />

the internal market against illegal trade. <strong>The</strong> reasons for this are detailed in the <strong>Viet</strong>namese section of<br />

this report, which addresses the current situation within that end-user market.<br />

Another related concern is that a legal rhino horn supply could be seen to legitimize or encourage rhino<br />

horn use which might actually increase demand at different scales or encourage speculation, especially if<br />

legal horn is suddenly available at reduced prices. Because current levels of demand and consumption in<br />

<strong>Viet</strong> <strong>Nam</strong> and elsewhere are unknown (including the appearance of emerging illegal rhino horn utilization<br />

in China), demand expansion in the wake of a legal avenue of trade could potentially exacerbate the plethora<br />

of problems associated with the present illegal horn trade. Instead of decreasing demand for rhino horn,<br />

if increasing supply of legal horn at reduced prices actually stimulates a far greater number of consumers to<br />

purchase horn, and this leads to a rising demand that is difficult to supply with legal sources of horn, the<br />

activation of legal trade would be self-defeating in terms of reducing poaching pressure on rhinos. Some<br />

have also expressed moral concerns that providing a legal supply of rhino horn would tacitly legitimize current<br />

non-traditional uses, for example the treatment of fatal illnesses such as cancer, and that this is ethically<br />

wrong in the absence of clinical trials and scientific evidence attesting to the efficacy of such remedies.<br />

A paramount concern of many observers is the possibility of laundering illegal horns from poached rhinos<br />

into a legal market. Such a development could equally impact on other rhino range States in <strong>Africa</strong><br />

and Asia, as well as <strong>South</strong> <strong>Africa</strong>. <strong>The</strong>re are many instances of wildlife commodity trade where legal and<br />

illegal trades have existed in parallel, and export, wholesale or retail dealers have had access to both<br />

sources of trade. In some cases, legal commerce has been undermined by the illegal trade over time,<br />

including the caviar trade from Central Asia (Vaisman and Fomenko, 2006; de Meulenaer and<br />

Raymakers, 1996), <strong>Africa</strong>n Grey Parrots from Central <strong>Africa</strong> (Mulliken, 1995), the abalone trade from<br />

<strong>South</strong> <strong>Africa</strong> (Plagányi et al., 2011; Raemaekers et al., 2011), the snake skin trade from Indonesia<br />

(Nijman and Shepherd, 2009), and most recently the ivory trade in China (Martin and Vigne, 2011).<br />

Issues of price, availability and quality are important considerations in the legal vs illegal trade equation.<br />

<strong>The</strong> fact that rhino horn will most likely change form into a generic, nondescript powder in the<br />

end-use market presents a further challenging dimension for the development of an effective identification,<br />

monitoring and law enforcement system that precludes laundering of illicit horn into the trade.<br />

Given the challenges and the complexity that any workable system would necessarily entail, some<br />

question remains as to whether the kind of political will and oversight capabilities of potential user<br />

countries are sufficient to monitor and police such a trade effectively. For example, to date, <strong>Viet</strong> <strong>Nam</strong><br />

seems unwilling or unable to control and monitor its hunting trophy imports, or to police its internal<br />

markets in spite of legal prohibitions making commercial trade in rhino horn illegal.<br />

Within <strong>South</strong> <strong>Africa</strong>, a similar host of issues remain unresolved. Some have argued that unresolved issues<br />

vis-à-vis provincial permitting practices, the failure to implement TOPS regulations in all provinces, ongoing<br />

rhino horn stock registration problems and other lapses in government regulation and oversight do<br />

not bode well for the implementation of a legal trade regime in the country. <strong>South</strong> <strong>Africa</strong> needs to demonstrate<br />

a functional and integrated national permitting and information management system for rhinos.<br />

Others draw attention to the failure of many private sector stakeholders to provide information on<br />

numbers of rhinos on their properties and horn stockpiles in their possession. Some conservationists also<br />

have concerns that opening a legal trade supply may encourage farmers to selectively breed White <strong>Rhino</strong>s<br />

specifically for their horns, resulting in semi-domestication, giving rise to potential animal welfare issues<br />

and resulting in a genetic skew within farmed rhino populations.<br />

As the full range of specifics for the practical arrangements necessary for implementation of a successful<br />

legal trade regime remain unclear at best, it remains difficult to thoughtfully examine the legal rhino<br />

horn trade issue until it moves beyond the realm of unresolved priorities and experimental theories.<br />

104 the south africa <strong>–</strong> viet nam rhino horn trade nexus TRAFFIC 105

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!