19.04.2014 Views

Eco Today - Mar10:ET Master Page 2007 - ASKnLearn

Eco Today - Mar10:ET Master Page 2007 - ASKnLearn

Eco Today - Mar10:ET Master Page 2007 - ASKnLearn

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

said to epitomise how big government<br />

and economic success can run hand in<br />

hand. Closer inspection reveals a<br />

somewhat different interpretation.<br />

First, there is the counterfactual.<br />

These economies could well have<br />

achieved even faster growth in the<br />

absence of a large state. Second, many<br />

of these economies have reduced the<br />

size of the state significantly e.g.<br />

Sweden where public spending fell from<br />

71 to 51 per cent of GDP over the 1992-<br />

<strong>2007</strong> period (before the current financial<br />

and economic crisis took hold).<br />

The damaging potential impact of<br />

higher taxation (to finance higher spend -<br />

ing) on economic activity is best under -<br />

stood with the concept of deadweight<br />

cost.<br />

The deadweight cost of taxation is<br />

the loss of output which would have<br />

occurred in the absence of the tax – a<br />

loss of economic welfare above and<br />

beyond the tax revenues collected. The<br />

loss of economic welfare arises from the<br />

disincentive effect of taxation on labour<br />

supply and saving.<br />

Deadweight loss is the ultimate stealth<br />

tax. No one sees the extra output that<br />

would have been created by economic<br />

decisions made in the absence of higher<br />

taxes.<br />

This means that an extra £1 of govern -<br />

ment spending costs the economy more<br />

than £1 and hence reducing taxes by £1<br />

generates more than £1 of benefit to the<br />

economy.<br />

How should spending<br />

reduction be undertaken?<br />

Standard slicing off every departmental<br />

budget is the wrong thing to do. There<br />

needs to be a fundamental root and<br />

branch appraisal of all spending, which<br />

is also informed by public choice theory.<br />

Public choice theory highlights the<br />

self-interest of public servants who may<br />

have their own agenda and little or no<br />

incentive to roll back the state. Senior<br />

civil servants may well need to receive<br />

personal incentives in order for them<br />

actively to support reduced public<br />

spend ing and productivity increasing<br />

reforms.<br />

Whilst not a perfect illustration,<br />

Canadian experience of zero-based<br />

budgeting in the 1990s shows that<br />

deep inroads into public spending<br />

can be made. The public spending<br />

to GDP ratio fell from 53 per cent in<br />

1992 to 39 per cent in <strong>2007</strong> (before the<br />

current financial and economic crisis<br />

took hold). Indeed, between 1992 (the<br />

year of the largest deficit) and 1997 (the<br />

first year of surplus), spending fell by<br />

9 percentage points of GDP, while the<br />

tax/GDP ratio rose by just 0.3 per -<br />

centage points.<br />

When should the next<br />

Chancellor start reducing<br />

spending?<br />

The answer is sooner rather than later.<br />

The obvious immediate critique is that<br />

reducing spending during a recession<br />

or infant recovery will only reduce<br />

aggregate demand. However, the reality<br />

is more nuanced.<br />

Experience of the March 1981 Budget<br />

shows that fiscal policy can be tightened<br />

during a recession, if monetary policy is<br />

simultaneously eased.<br />

The economy may also display<br />

‘Ricardian equivalence’ – when<br />

households see rising budget deficits as<br />

a portent of future tax increases and<br />

merely raise their levels of current saving<br />

to provision for this eventuality.<br />

The academic literature is somewhat<br />

mixed, but it would appear that at certain<br />

times this effect can be much more<br />

significant and pre-announcing a<br />

credible fiscal adjustment, based on<br />

lower public spending, might actually<br />

boost activity. This may well be one of<br />

those times, given the scale of media<br />

coverage on the recession and fiscal<br />

deficit.<br />

The current fiscal crisis is presenting<br />

what may be a once in a generation<br />

opportunity to tighten dramatically<br />

public spending whilst simultaneously<br />

maintaining GDP growth during the<br />

transition phase to higher long-term<br />

growth, by retaining zero bound interest<br />

rates.<br />

Looking further into the 21st century,<br />

one can speculate that the pressure to<br />

reduce public spending – because of the<br />

negative impact of the taxation required<br />

to fund it – will steadily increase for a<br />

number of reasons.<br />

First, the effect of globalisation, with<br />

mobile factors of production and<br />

electronic commerce, threatens to<br />

heighten tax competition as part of the<br />

process to attract footloose foreign<br />

investment.<br />

Second, long term real income growth<br />

may result in future middle income<br />

households behaving more like upper<br />

income households at present. As a<br />

result, their labour supply may become<br />

more sensitive to post tax income.<br />

It is very difficult to be precise when<br />

speculating on the optimal size of public<br />

The pressure to<br />

reduce public spending<br />

will steadily increase.<br />

spending in the UK. One very robust<br />

conclusion, however, can still be drawn.<br />

The threshold at which the relationship<br />

between public spending and economic<br />

growth becomes negative is dramati -<br />

cally lower than the spending ratio at<br />

present.<br />

Given the potential trade-off between<br />

lower spending, reduced taxation and<br />

faster GDP growth, consideration of the<br />

thoughts of John Maynard Keynes might<br />

be helpful. Commenting on the tax<br />

burden required to fund public spending<br />

Keynes speculated that:<br />

❝…25 per cent as the maximum<br />

tolerable proportion of taxation may<br />

be exceedingly near the truth.<br />

When considering the size of the state,<br />

we have tolerated too much for too long.<br />

A 35 per cent target for the spending to<br />

GDP ratio by 2020 should not be seen<br />

as the full solution. We would recom -<br />

mend a policy objective of 30 per cent<br />

by 2025.<br />

Without this approach, the UK<br />

economy risks becoming the sick man<br />

of Europe, with low trend growth and<br />

high levels of public spending and<br />

taxation.<br />

M ARCH 2010 19

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!