12.07.2015 Views

Poverty and Inequality in India: a Reexamination - Princeton University

Poverty and Inequality in India: a Reexamination - Princeton University

Poverty and Inequality in India: a Reexamination - Princeton University

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

eal terms, with updat<strong>in</strong>g on the basis ofapproximate price <strong>in</strong>dexes such as theWholesale Price Index or the CSO’s privateconsumption deflator. The <strong>in</strong>itial ruralurbangap of 15 per cent is anchored <strong>in</strong>1973-74 calorie consumption data, but itis essentially arbitrary s<strong>in</strong>ce the urban <strong>and</strong>rural ‘calorie norms’ themselves (2,100<strong>and</strong> 2,400 calories per person per day,respectively) have a fragile basis. 8 Morerecently, the Plann<strong>in</strong>g Commission hasadopted a modified version of the povertyl<strong>in</strong>es recommended by a 1993 Expert Group[Government of <strong>India</strong> 1993]. The ExpertGroup reta<strong>in</strong>ed the orig<strong>in</strong>al rural <strong>and</strong> urbanl<strong>in</strong>es, but adjusted them for statewisedifferences <strong>in</strong> price levels, separately forurban <strong>and</strong> rural sectors, us<strong>in</strong>g estimates ofstatewise price differences calculated fromNSS data on expenditures <strong>and</strong> quantitiesus<strong>in</strong>g similar methods to those adopted <strong>in</strong>this paper. The Expert Group l<strong>in</strong>es usedthe then best-available <strong>in</strong>formation on pricedifferences across states, both urban <strong>and</strong>rural, but the <strong>in</strong>formation was outdated,especially for the rural sector.Because the statewise adjustments weredone separately for urban <strong>and</strong> rural households,the price differences between theurban <strong>and</strong> rural sectors of each state werederived only implicitly, <strong>and</strong> some are ratherimplausible, particularly the very muchhigher urban than rural l<strong>in</strong>es <strong>in</strong> severalstates. For example, the most recent urbanpoverty l<strong>in</strong>es for Andhra Pradesh <strong>and</strong>Karnataka are around 70 per cent higherthan the correspond<strong>in</strong>g rural l<strong>in</strong>es, with theuncomfortable result that urban poverty ismuch higher than rural poverty <strong>in</strong> thesetwo states (see Table 2 <strong>in</strong> the next section).In Assam, by contrast, the rural povertyl<strong>in</strong>e is actually higher than the urban l<strong>in</strong>e,<strong>and</strong> based on these odd poverty l<strong>in</strong>es, Assamturns out to be one of <strong>India</strong>’s highestpovertystates for rural areas but lowestpovertystates for urban areas. It is hardto accept these <strong>and</strong> other implications ofthe Expert Group poverty l<strong>in</strong>es.There are grounds, of course, for question<strong>in</strong>gwhether it is even possible to derivecomparable rural <strong>and</strong> urban poverty l<strong>in</strong>es.Comparisons of liv<strong>in</strong>g st<strong>and</strong>ards <strong>in</strong> rural<strong>and</strong> urban areas are <strong>in</strong>herently difficult,s<strong>in</strong>ce there are large <strong>in</strong>tersectoral differencesnot only <strong>in</strong> the patterns of consumptionbut also <strong>in</strong> lifestyles, public amenities,epidemiological environments, <strong>and</strong> so on.One way forward is to avoid such comparisonsaltogether, <strong>and</strong> to focus on sectorspecific(rural or urban) poverty estimates.Yet there is a case for attempt<strong>in</strong>g tocompare private consumption levels acrosssectors, bear<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> m<strong>in</strong>d that this is at besta partial picture of the relevant differences<strong>in</strong> liv<strong>in</strong>g st<strong>and</strong>ards. 9 These comparisonscan be made by anchor<strong>in</strong>g poverty estimates<strong>in</strong> a s<strong>in</strong>gle poverty l<strong>in</strong>e, adjusted whereappropriate to take <strong>in</strong>to account rural-urbanprice differences, us<strong>in</strong>g the same methodas that described earlier for adjust<strong>in</strong>gpoverty l<strong>in</strong>es over time <strong>and</strong> between states.Based on this procedure, the urban povertyl<strong>in</strong>e tends be about 15 per cent higher thanthe rural poverty l<strong>in</strong>e, though there arevariations across states. As it turns out, thisrural-urban difference <strong>in</strong> poverty l<strong>in</strong>es isbroadly consistent with the orig<strong>in</strong>almethodology used before the adoption ofthe Expert Group recommendations.To recapitulate, the revised poverty l<strong>in</strong>esused <strong>in</strong> this paper, which are presented <strong>in</strong>full <strong>in</strong> Table 4 of Deaton (2001b), arederived as follows. Our start<strong>in</strong>g po<strong>in</strong>t isthe official rural all-<strong>India</strong> poverty l<strong>in</strong>e forthe 43rd Round (1987-88): 115.70 rupeesper person per month. 10 Rural povertyl<strong>in</strong>es for each state for the 43rd Round areobta<strong>in</strong>ed by multiply<strong>in</strong>g this base povertyl<strong>in</strong>e by the rural price <strong>in</strong>dexes for each staterelative to all-<strong>India</strong>. The urban povertyl<strong>in</strong>es for the 43rd Round, for each state aswell as for all-<strong>India</strong>, are calculated fromthe rural poverty l<strong>in</strong>es by scal<strong>in</strong>g up by therespective urban relative to rural price<strong>in</strong>dexes. In all cases, we use the relevantTörnqvist price <strong>in</strong>dexes. 11 To move to the50th Round, the orig<strong>in</strong>al all-<strong>India</strong> rurall<strong>in</strong>e, 115.70 rupees, is scaled up by theTörnqvist <strong>in</strong>dex for all-<strong>India</strong> rural for the50th Round relative to the 43rd Round,1.698, to give an all-<strong>India</strong> rural povertyl<strong>in</strong>e for the 50th Round. This number isthen used to generate rural <strong>and</strong> then urbanpoverty l<strong>in</strong>es for each state, follow<strong>in</strong>gexactly the same procedure as for the 43rdRound. F<strong>in</strong>ally, poverty l<strong>in</strong>es for the 55thRound are calculated <strong>in</strong> the same way froman all-<strong>India</strong> rural l<strong>in</strong>e, which is the 50thRound all-<strong>India</strong> rural l<strong>in</strong>e scaled up by thevalue of the Törnqvist <strong>in</strong>dex between thetwo surveys. 12The motivation for the fourth departure(or rather extension) arises from the limitationsof the headcount ratio as an <strong>in</strong>dicatorof poverty. The headcount ratio hasa straightforward <strong>in</strong>terpretation <strong>and</strong> is easyto underst<strong>and</strong>. In that sense it has much‘communication value’. Yet, the HCR hasserious limitations as a poverty <strong>in</strong>dex. Forone th<strong>in</strong>g, it ignores the extent to whichdifferent households fall short of thepoverty l<strong>in</strong>e. This leads to some perverseproperties. For <strong>in</strong>stance, an <strong>in</strong>come transferfrom a very poor person to someonewho is closer to the poverty l<strong>in</strong>e may leadto a decl<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong> the headcount ratio, ifit ‘lifts’ the recipient above the povertyl<strong>in</strong>e. Similarly, if some poor householdsget poorer, this has no effect on theheadcount ratio.A related issue is that changes <strong>in</strong> HCRscan be highly sensitive to the number ofpoor households near the poverty l<strong>in</strong>e (s<strong>in</strong>cechanges <strong>in</strong> the HCR are entirely driven by‘cross<strong>in</strong>gs’ of the poverty l<strong>in</strong>e). If poorhouseholds are heavily ‘bunched’ near thepoverty l<strong>in</strong>e, a small <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> averageper capita <strong>in</strong>come could lead to a mislead<strong>in</strong>glylarge decl<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong> the headcount ratio.This ‘density effect’ has to be kept firmly<strong>in</strong> view <strong>in</strong> the context of comparisons ofpoverty change, <strong>in</strong>volv<strong>in</strong>g questions suchas “has there been more poverty decl<strong>in</strong>e<strong>in</strong> Bihar than <strong>in</strong> Punjab dur<strong>in</strong>g the n<strong>in</strong>eties”,or “has poverty decl<strong>in</strong>ed faster <strong>in</strong> then<strong>in</strong>eties than <strong>in</strong> the eighties?” Often suchquestions are answered by look<strong>in</strong>g at, say,the respective changes (absolute or proportionate)<strong>in</strong> headcount ratios. Thesechanges, however, are difficult to <strong>in</strong>terpret<strong>in</strong> the absence of further <strong>in</strong>formation aboutthe <strong>in</strong>itial density of poor households nearthe poverty l<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong> each case.One way forward is to use more sophisticatedpoverty <strong>in</strong>dexes such as the Foster-Greer-Thorbecke (FGT) <strong>in</strong>dexes or the Sen<strong>in</strong>dex. In this paper, we focus on the simplestmember of the FGT class (other thanthe headcount ratio itself), the ‘povertygap<strong>in</strong>dex’. Essentially, the poverty-gap<strong>in</strong>dex (hereafter PGI) is the aggregateshortfall of poor people’s consumptionfrom the poverty l<strong>in</strong>e, suitably normalised.13 The PGI can also be <strong>in</strong>terpreted asthe headcount ratio multiplied by the meanpercentage shortfall of consumption fromthe poverty l<strong>in</strong>e (among the poor). This<strong>in</strong>dex avoids the ma<strong>in</strong> shortcom<strong>in</strong>gs of theheadcount ratio, is relatively simple tocalculate, <strong>and</strong> has a straightforward <strong>in</strong>terpretation.14I.3 Adjusted EstimatesTable 1a presents official <strong>and</strong> adjustedestimates of the all-<strong>India</strong> headcount ratio.In each panel, the first row gives the officialestimates; the second row reta<strong>in</strong>s the officialpoverty l<strong>in</strong>es but adjusts the 1999-2000 estimates for the change <strong>in</strong> questionnairedesign <strong>in</strong> the way described earlier;the third row gives fully-adjusted povertyestimates, which comb<strong>in</strong>e the adjustmentsEconomic <strong>and</strong> Political Weekly September 7, 2002 3733


for questionnaire design <strong>and</strong> for price <strong>in</strong>dexes.Table 1b gives the correspond<strong>in</strong>gpoverty-gap <strong>in</strong>dexes.As the first two rows of each panel<strong>in</strong>dicate, the official estimates are quitemislead<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> their own terms: the 1999-2000 poverty estimates are biased downwardby the changes <strong>in</strong> questionnairedesign. For headcount ratios, the estimatesadjusted for changes <strong>in</strong> questionnairedesign ‘confirm’ about two-thirds of theofficial decl<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong> rural poverty between1993-94 <strong>and</strong> 1999-2000, <strong>and</strong> about 90 percent of the decl<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong> urban poverty. Forpoverty-gap <strong>in</strong>dexes, the correspond<strong>in</strong>gproportions (62 per cent <strong>and</strong> 77 per cent)are lower, especially for the urban sector.The fully-adjusted estimates <strong>in</strong> the lastrow of each panel show somewhat lowerrural poverty estimates <strong>and</strong> much lowerurban poverty estimates for 1999-2000than even the official estimates. Note,however, that because we are recalculat<strong>in</strong>gthe poverty l<strong>in</strong>es back to the 43rd Round,a good deal of the decrease took place <strong>in</strong>the six years prior to 1993-94, not only <strong>in</strong>the six years subsequent to 1993-94. Thefully-adjusted estimates for the headcountratios <strong>and</strong> poverty gap <strong>in</strong>dexes suggest thatpoverty decl<strong>in</strong>e has been fairly evenlyspread between the two sub-periods (before<strong>and</strong> after 1993-94), <strong>in</strong> contrast withthe pattern of ‘acceleration’ <strong>in</strong> the secondsub-period associated with the officialestimates.The rural-urban gaps <strong>in</strong> the povertyestimates are also of <strong>in</strong>terest. Look<strong>in</strong>g firstat the base year (1987-88), the rural-urbangap based on adjusted estimates is muchlarger than that based on official estimates.Indeed, the latter suggest no differencebetween rural <strong>and</strong> urban poverty <strong>in</strong> thatyear. This is hard to reconcile with <strong>in</strong>dependentevidence on liv<strong>in</strong>g conditions <strong>in</strong>rural <strong>and</strong> urban areas, such as a lifeexpectancygap of about seven years <strong>in</strong>favour or urban areas around that time. 15Our low estimate of the urban headcountratio relative to the official estimate (22.5per cent versus 39.1 per cent), <strong>and</strong> similardifferences <strong>in</strong> 1993-94 <strong>and</strong> 1999-2000,come from the fact that we take the ruralpoverty l<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong> 1987-88 as our start<strong>in</strong>gpo<strong>in</strong>t, <strong>and</strong> peg the urban poverty l<strong>in</strong>esabout 15 per cent higher than the ruralpoverty l<strong>in</strong>es, <strong>in</strong> contrast to the much largerdifferentials embodied <strong>in</strong> the official l<strong>in</strong>es.Figure 1 shows the new estimates of theheadcount ratios together with the officialestimates go<strong>in</strong>g back to 1973-74. The fullyadjusted figures are lower throughoutHeadcount ratio (per cent)6050403020Figure 1: Official <strong>and</strong> Adjusted Headcounts Ratios1970 1980 1990 2000YearSource: Plann<strong>in</strong>g Commission, Press Releases ( March 11, 1997, <strong>and</strong> February 22, 2001), Deaton (2001a,b), <strong>and</strong> Table 2a of this paper.because we treat the rural poverty l<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong>the 43rd Round as our basel<strong>in</strong>e so that,with larger rural-urban gaps <strong>in</strong> the povertyestimates, we estimate lower povertyoverall. If <strong>in</strong>stead, we had taken the urbanpoverty l<strong>in</strong>e as base, the adjusted figureswould have been higher than the officialfigures. From 1987-88 to 1993-94, theadjusted headcount ratio falls more rapidlythan the official headcount; this is becauseour price deflators are ris<strong>in</strong>g less rapidlythan the official ones. From 1993-94, theadjusted figures fall more slowly becausethe effects of the price adjustment are morethan offset by the correction for questionnairedesign. The estimates for the th<strong>in</strong>rounds – which look very different – are<strong>in</strong>cluded to rem<strong>in</strong>d us of the residualuncerta<strong>in</strong>ty about our conclusions, <strong>and</strong>will be discussed further <strong>in</strong> Section IV.3below.I.4 Regional ContrastsState-specific headcount ratios are presented<strong>in</strong> Table 2a. 16 The table has thesame basic structure as Table 1a, exceptthat we jump straight from official to fullyadjustedestimates. The latter suggest thatthe basic pattern of susta<strong>in</strong>ed povertydecl<strong>in</strong>e between 1987-88 <strong>and</strong> 1999-2000,discussed earlier at the all-<strong>India</strong> level, alsoapplies at the level of <strong>in</strong>dividual states <strong>in</strong>most cases. The ma<strong>in</strong> exception is Assam,where poverty has stagnated <strong>in</strong> both rural<strong>and</strong> urban areas. In Orissa, there has beenvery little poverty decl<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong> the secondsub-period, with the result that Orissa nowOfficial countsAdjusted countsTh<strong>in</strong> roundshas the highest level of rural poverty amongall <strong>India</strong>n states, accord<strong>in</strong>g to the adjusted1999-2000 estimates. 17 Reassur<strong>in</strong>gly, the‘anomalies’ noted earlier with respect torural-urban gaps <strong>in</strong> specific states tend todisappear as one moves from official toadjusted estimates.Table 2b shows the correspond<strong>in</strong>g poverty-gap<strong>in</strong>dexes. The general patterns arevery much the same as with headcountratios; <strong>in</strong>deed the PGI series are highlycorrelated with the correspond<strong>in</strong>g HCRseries, with correlation coefficients of 0.98for rural <strong>and</strong> 0.95 for urban. Even the HCR<strong>and</strong> PGI changes between the 50th <strong>and</strong>55th Rounds are highly correlated; thecorrelation coefficient between changes <strong>in</strong>HCR <strong>and</strong> changes <strong>in</strong> PGI is 0.95 for therural sector, <strong>and</strong> 0.96 for the urban sector.Thus, <strong>in</strong> spite of its theoretical superiorityover the headcount ratio, the poverty-gap<strong>in</strong>dex gives us very little additional <strong>in</strong>sight<strong>in</strong> this case.In <strong>in</strong>terpret<strong>in</strong>g <strong>and</strong> compar<strong>in</strong>g povertydecl<strong>in</strong>es over time, it is useful to supplementthe poverty <strong>in</strong>dexes with <strong>in</strong>formationon the growth rate of average per capitaconsumption expenditure (hereafterAPCE). State-specific estimates of APCEgrowth between 1993-94 <strong>and</strong> 1999-2000are shown <strong>in</strong> Table 3, where states areranked <strong>in</strong> ascend<strong>in</strong>g order of APCE growthfor rural <strong>and</strong> urban areas comb<strong>in</strong>ed. 18Here, a strik<strong>in</strong>g regional pattern emerges:except for Jammu <strong>and</strong> Kashmir, the lowgrowthstates form one contiguous regionmade up of the eastern states (Assam,Orissa <strong>and</strong> West Bengal), the so-called3734Economic <strong>and</strong> Political Weekly September 7, 2002


Figure 2: ‘Divergence’ of Per Capita Expenditure Across States, 1993-94 to 1999-00Average annual growth (per cent)6420BIORMPUPASKA200 300 400 500 600Source: Authors’ calculations us<strong>in</strong>g unit record data from the 50th <strong>and</strong> 55th Rounds of the National SampleSurvey.AI = All <strong>India</strong>; AP = Andhra Pradesh; AS = Assam; BI = Bihar; DE = Delhi; GU = Gujarat; HA = Haryana;HP = Himachal Pradesh; JK = Jammu <strong>and</strong> Kashmir; KA = Karnataka; KE = Kerala; MA = Maharashtra;MP = Madhya Pradesh; OR = Orissa; PU = Punjab; RA = Rajasthan; TN = Tamil Nadu; UP = Uttar Pradesh;WB = West Bengal.BIMARU states (Bihar, Madhya Pradesh,Rajasthan <strong>and</strong> Uttar Pradesh), <strong>and</strong> AndhraPradesh. The high-growth states, for theirpart, consist of the southern states (exceptAndhra Pradesh), the western states(Gujarat <strong>and</strong> Maharashtra) <strong>and</strong> the northwesternregion (Punjab, Haryana <strong>and</strong>Himachal Pradesh). Further, it is <strong>in</strong>terest<strong>in</strong>gto note that this pattern is reasonablyconsistent with <strong>in</strong>dependent data on growthrates of per capita ‘state domestic product’(SDP); these are shown <strong>in</strong> the last columnof Table 3. With a couple of exceptionson each side, all the states <strong>in</strong> the ‘lowAPCE growth’ set had comparatively lowrates of per capita SDP between 1993-94<strong>and</strong> 1999-2000 (say below 4 per cent peryear), <strong>and</strong> conversely, all the states <strong>in</strong> the‘high APCE growth’ set had comparativelyhigh annual growth rates of percapita SDP (the correlation coefficientbetween the two series is 0.45). 19This broad regional pattern is a matterof concern, because the low-growth statesalso tend to be states that started off withcomparatively low levels of APCE or percapitaSDP. In other words, there has beena grow<strong>in</strong>g ‘divergence’ of per capita expenditure(<strong>and</strong> also of per capita SDP)AIAPWBTNMAGURAHPHAKEJKPUGeometric mean PCE <strong>in</strong> 1993-94, rupees per headDEacross <strong>India</strong>n states <strong>in</strong> the n<strong>in</strong>eties. 20 Thepo<strong>in</strong>t is illustrated <strong>in</strong> Figure 2, which plotsthe average growth <strong>in</strong> APCE for each statebetween 1993-94 <strong>and</strong> 1999-2000 aga<strong>in</strong>stthe geometric mean of APCE <strong>in</strong> 1993-94.It is worth ask<strong>in</strong>g to what extent theseregional patterns, based on APCE data, arecorroborated by regional patterns of povertydecl<strong>in</strong>e. One difficulty here is thatthere is no obvious way of ‘compar<strong>in</strong>g’ theextent of poverty decl<strong>in</strong>e across states. For<strong>in</strong>stance, look<strong>in</strong>g at absolute changes <strong>in</strong>(say) HCRs would seem to give an unfair‘advantage’ to states that start off withhigh levels of poverty, <strong>and</strong> where theretends be a large number of householdsclose to the poverty l<strong>in</strong>e. To illustrate, theabsolute decl<strong>in</strong>e of the rural HCR between1993-94 <strong>and</strong> 1999-2000 was about twiceas large <strong>in</strong> Bihar (7.4 percentage po<strong>in</strong>ts)as <strong>in</strong> Punjab (3.8 po<strong>in</strong>ts), yet over the sameperiod APCE grew by only 6.9 per cent<strong>in</strong> Bihar compared with 20.2 per cent<strong>in</strong> Punjab, with virtually no change <strong>in</strong>distribution <strong>in</strong> either case. 21 The reasonfor this contrast is that Bihar starts off <strong>in</strong>1993-94 with a very high proportion ofhouseholds close to the poverty l<strong>in</strong>e, sothat small <strong>in</strong>creases <strong>in</strong> APCE can producerelatively large absolute decl<strong>in</strong>es <strong>in</strong> theheadcount ratio.An alternative approach is to look atproportionate changes <strong>in</strong> HCRs or PGIs.These turn out to be highly correlated withthe correspond<strong>in</strong>g growth rates of APCE.The po<strong>in</strong>t is illustrated <strong>in</strong> Figure 3, wherewe plot the proportionate decl<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong> therural headcount ratio <strong>in</strong> each state aga<strong>in</strong>stthe growth rate of APCE <strong>in</strong> rural areas. Thecorrelation coefficient between the twoseries is as high as 0.91. This reflects thefact that poverty reduction is overwhelm<strong>in</strong>glydriven by the growth rate of APCE,rather than by changes <strong>in</strong> distribution – weshall return to this po<strong>in</strong>t <strong>in</strong> Section III.From these observations, it follows that ifwe accept ‘proportionate change <strong>in</strong> HCR’(or PGI) as an <strong>in</strong>dex of poverty reduction,then the broad regional patterns identifiedearlier for the growth rate of APCE alsotend to apply to poverty reduction. Inparticular: (1) most of the western <strong>and</strong>southern states (with the important exceptionof Andhra Pradesh) have done comparativelywell; (2) the eastern region hasachieved very little poverty reductionbetween 1993-94 <strong>and</strong> 1999-2000; <strong>and</strong>(3) there is a strong overall pattern of ‘divergence’(states that were poorer to startwith had lower rates of poverty reduction).This read<strong>in</strong>g of the evidence, however,rema<strong>in</strong>s somewhat tentative, s<strong>in</strong>ce there isno compell<strong>in</strong>g reason to accept the proportionatedecl<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong> HCR (or PGI) as adef<strong>in</strong>itive measure of poverty decl<strong>in</strong>e.We end this section with a caveat. FromTable 2 <strong>and</strong> Figure 1, it may appear thatthe ‘pace’ of poverty decl<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong> the n<strong>in</strong>etieshas been fairly rapid. It is important tonote, however, that the associated <strong>in</strong>creases<strong>in</strong> per capita expenditure have been rathermodest <strong>in</strong> most cases. For <strong>in</strong>stance, thedecl<strong>in</strong>e of 6.6 percentage po<strong>in</strong>ts <strong>in</strong> the all-<strong>India</strong> HCR (from 29.2 per cent to 22.7 percent) between 1993-94 <strong>and</strong> 1999-2000 isdriven by an <strong>in</strong>crease of only 10.9 per cent<strong>in</strong> average per capita expenditure – notexactly a spectacular improvement <strong>in</strong>liv<strong>in</strong>g st<strong>and</strong>ards. Similarly, Table 2a suggeststhat Bihar achieved a large step <strong>in</strong>poverty reduction <strong>in</strong> the n<strong>in</strong>eties, with therural HCR com<strong>in</strong>g down from 49 per centto 41 per cent. Yet, as Table 3 <strong>in</strong>dicates,average APCE <strong>in</strong> rural Bihar <strong>in</strong>creasedby only 7 per cent between 1993-94 <strong>and</strong>1999-2000.Why are small <strong>in</strong>creases <strong>in</strong> APCE associatedwith substantial decl<strong>in</strong>es <strong>in</strong> poverty<strong>in</strong>dexes? It is tempt<strong>in</strong>g to answer that thedistribution of consumer expenditureEconomic <strong>and</strong> Political Weekly September 7, 2002 3735


must have improved <strong>in</strong> the n<strong>in</strong>eties. Asdiscussed <strong>in</strong> Section III, however, this isnot the case: <strong>in</strong>deed economic <strong>in</strong>equalityhas <strong>in</strong>creased rather than decreased <strong>in</strong> then<strong>in</strong>eties. The correct answer relates to the‘density effect’ mentioned earlier (seeSection I.2): when many poor householdsare close to the poverty l<strong>in</strong>e, modest <strong>in</strong>creases<strong>in</strong> APCE can produce substantialdecl<strong>in</strong>es <strong>in</strong> st<strong>and</strong>ard poverty <strong>in</strong>dexes. Onereason for draw<strong>in</strong>g attention to this is thatthe official poverty estimates have sometimesbeen used to claim that the n<strong>in</strong>etieshave been a period of spectacular achievements<strong>in</strong> poverty reduction. In fact, whenthe relevant adjustments are made, <strong>and</strong>the poverty <strong>in</strong>dexes are read together withthe <strong>in</strong>formation on APCE growth, povertyreduction <strong>in</strong> the n<strong>in</strong>eties appears to bemore or less <strong>in</strong> l<strong>in</strong>e with previous rates ofprogress.IIFurther EvidenceII.1 National Accounts StatisticsThere has been much discussion of theconsistency between National SampleSurvey data <strong>and</strong> the ‘national accounts’published by the Central StatisticalOrganisation (CSO). 22 The latter <strong>in</strong>cludeestimates of ‘private f<strong>in</strong>al consumer expenditure’,which is frequently comparedwith NSS estimates of ‘household(Rural)consumption expenditure’. Over time, theCSO estimates have tended to grow fasterthan the NSS estimates, lead<strong>in</strong>g some commentatorsto question the reliability ofNational Sample Survey data.It is important to note that these twonotions of ‘consumer expenditure’ are notTable 3: Growth Rates of APCE <strong>and</strong> Per Capita SDP, 1993-94 to 1999-2000Six-Year Growth of APCE (‘Adjusted’), 1993-94 to 1999-2000 Annual Growth Rate ofRural Urban Comb<strong>in</strong>ed Per Capita SDP,1993-94 to 1999-2000Assam 0.9 8.8 1.7 0.58Orissa 1.4 –0.0 3.3 2.34West Bengal 2.1 11.5 3.3 5.48Jammu <strong>and</strong> Kashmir 5.4 8.0 5.3 2.49Bihar 6.9 4.8 7.1 2.10Madhya Pradesh 6.6 14.1 7.8 2.78Andhra Pradesh 2.8 18.5 8.3 3.57Rajasthan 7.0 15.4 8.6 4.60Uttar Pradesh 8.3 10.1 9.0 2.99<strong>India</strong> 8.7 16.6 10.9 4.36Karnataka 9.5 26.5 14.0 5.82Maharashtra 14.1 16.7 15.9 3.53Gujarat 15.1 20.9 16.8 4.88Himachal Pradesh 16.2 28.5 17.6 5.06Tamil Nadu 15.7 25.1 18.9 5.39Kerala 19.6 18.2 19.6 4.01Punjab 20.2 17.9 19.9 2.74Haryana 31.0 23.0 29.2 3.05Delhi – 30.7 30.7 5.69Note: The states are arranged <strong>in</strong> ascend<strong>in</strong>g order of the growth rate of APCE for rural <strong>and</strong> urban areacomb<strong>in</strong>ed.Sources: For APCE: Authors’ calculations from unit record data for the 50th <strong>and</strong> 55th Rounds of the NationalSample Survey. For SDP: Authors’ calculations based on unpublished data k<strong>in</strong>dly supplied by thePlann<strong>in</strong>g Commission. The figures <strong>in</strong> the last column should be taken as <strong>in</strong>dicative, given thesignificant marg<strong>in</strong> of error <strong>in</strong>volved <strong>in</strong> SDP estimates.Proportionate decl<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong> rural headcount ratio706050403020100–10Figure 3: HCR Decl<strong>in</strong>es <strong>and</strong> APCE Growth, 1993-94 to 1999-2000ASWBORAP0 5 10 15 20 25 30Source: Tables 2a <strong>and</strong> 3.JKRA UPINDIABI KAMPGUMAHPTNSix-year growth of rural APCEKEPUHAexactly the same, <strong>and</strong> also that there aremajor methodological differences betweenthe two sources. The NSS figures are directestimates of household consumption expenditure.The CSO figures <strong>in</strong>clude severalitems of expenditure that are notcollected <strong>in</strong> the NSS surveys; examples areexpenditures by non-profit entreprises, aswell as imputed rent by owner occupiers<strong>and</strong> ‘f<strong>in</strong>ancial <strong>in</strong>termediation services<strong>in</strong>directly measured’ (the last item is essentiallythe net <strong>in</strong>terest earned by f<strong>in</strong>ancial<strong>in</strong>termediaries, which is counted asexpenditures on <strong>in</strong>termediation servicesby households). Accord<strong>in</strong>g to Sundaram<strong>and</strong> Tendulkar (2002), who quote a recentcross-validation study by the NationalAccounts Department, the last two itemsaccount for 22 per cent of the difference<strong>in</strong> levels between CSO <strong>and</strong> NSS estimatesof consumer expenditure. Further, the CSOestimates are ‘residual’ figures, obta<strong>in</strong>edafter subtract<strong>in</strong>g other items from thenational product. Leav<strong>in</strong>g aside thesecomparability issues, there is <strong>in</strong>deed a gapbetween the CSO-based <strong>and</strong> NSS-basedgrowth rates of consumer expenditure.Accord<strong>in</strong>g to CSO data, per-capita consumerexpenditure has grown at muchthe same rate as per capita GDP between1993-94 <strong>and</strong> 1999-2000 – about 3.5 percent per year <strong>in</strong> real terms. 23 The correspond<strong>in</strong>gNSS-based estimate associated3736Economic <strong>and</strong> Political Weekly September 7, 2002


n<strong>in</strong>eties. 28 Thus, real agricultural wageswere grow<strong>in</strong>g considerably faster <strong>in</strong> theeighties than <strong>in</strong> the n<strong>in</strong>eties. But even thereduced growth rate of agricultural wages<strong>in</strong> the n<strong>in</strong>eties, at 2.5 per cent per year,po<strong>in</strong>ts to significant growth of per capitaexpenditure among the poorer sections ofthe population <strong>and</strong> re<strong>in</strong>forces our earlierf<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>gs on poverty reduction. In fact, thisreduced growth rate is a little higher thanthe growth rate of average per capitaexpenditure (1.5 per cent per year) thatsusta<strong>in</strong>s our estimated decl<strong>in</strong>es of ruralheadcount ratios <strong>and</strong> headcount <strong>in</strong>dexesbetween 1993-94 <strong>and</strong> 1999-2000.The data on real wages also providesome <strong>in</strong>dependent corroboration of thestate-specific patterns of poverty decl<strong>in</strong>e.This is illustrated <strong>in</strong> Figure 5, where weplot state-specific estimates of the growthrate of real agricultural wages <strong>in</strong> the n<strong>in</strong>etiesaga<strong>in</strong>st the estimated proportionatedecl<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong> the headcount ratio (a very similarpattern applies to the poverty-gap <strong>in</strong>dex).Here the two ma<strong>in</strong> outliers are Punjab <strong>and</strong>Haryana, where the headcount ratio hasdecl<strong>in</strong>ed sharply without a correspond<strong>in</strong>glysharp <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> real wages (<strong>in</strong>deedwithout any such <strong>in</strong>crease, <strong>in</strong> the case ofPunjab). Leav<strong>in</strong>g out these two outliers,the association between the two series isremarkably close (with a correlation coefficientof 0.88).An <strong>in</strong>terest<strong>in</strong>g sidelight emerg<strong>in</strong>g fromFigure 5 is that a healthy growth of realagricultural wages appear to be a ‘sufficient’condition for substantial povertydecl<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong> rural areas: all the states wherereal wages have grown at more than, say,2.5 per cent per year <strong>in</strong> the n<strong>in</strong>eties haveexperienced a comparatively sharp reductionof the rural headcount ratio. Conversely,<strong>in</strong> states with low rates of reductionof the headcount ratio (say, 15 per centor less over six years), real wages have<strong>in</strong>variably grown at less than 2 per centper year. This applies <strong>in</strong> particular to theentire eastern region (Assam, Orissa, WestBengal <strong>and</strong> Bihar) <strong>and</strong> also to AndhraPradesh <strong>and</strong> Madhya Pradesh.Independent evidence on the growth ratesof real wages has recently been presentedby K Sundaram (2001a, 2001b), based onthe ‘employment-unemployment surveys’(EUS) of the National Sample Survey for1993-94 <strong>and</strong> 1999-2000. For the presentpurpose, these surveys are comparable.Sundaram estimates that the real earn<strong>in</strong>gsof agricultural labourers have grown atabout 2.5 per cent per year between 1993-94<strong>and</strong> 1999-2000. These are tentativeRural headcount ratio (adjusted)50403020100Figure 4: Agricultural Wages <strong>and</strong> Rural <strong>Poverty</strong>, 1999-2000ORKA0 2 3 4 5 6 7 8Real agricultural wageSource: Drèze <strong>and</strong> Sen (2002), Statistical Appendix, Table A 3, <strong>and</strong> Table 2a of this paper. The “realagricultural wage” is a three-year average end<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> 1999-2000.estimates, based as they are on data for twoyears only. Yet it is reassur<strong>in</strong>g to f<strong>in</strong>d thatthey are consistent with the AWI-basedestimates.II.3 The ‘Employment-Unemployment Surveys’The National Sample Survey’s 1993-94<strong>and</strong> 1999-2000 employment-unemploymentsurveys (EUS) also <strong>in</strong>clude consumerexpenditure data. These can be used forfurther scrut<strong>in</strong>y of poverty trends. Thistask has been undertaken <strong>in</strong> a recent paperby Sundaram <strong>and</strong> Tendulkar (2002). Theynote that the consumption survey <strong>in</strong> the1999-2000 EUS uses the traditional 30-day report<strong>in</strong>g period, but differs from thest<strong>and</strong>ard questionnaire by only ask<strong>in</strong>g anabbreviated set of questions. However, theauthors f<strong>in</strong>d that, <strong>in</strong> those cases where thequestions have comparable coverage, themeans from the EUS, us<strong>in</strong>g the traditional30-day report<strong>in</strong>g period, are typically closeto those from the 30-day questionnaire <strong>in</strong>the ma<strong>in</strong> consumption survey. Based onthis correspondence, they argue that the30-day questions <strong>in</strong> the ma<strong>in</strong> 1999-2000survey were not much distorted by theseven-day questions that were asked alongsidethem. In this version of events, themajor source of <strong>in</strong>comparability betweenthe 55th <strong>and</strong> 50th Rounds is not the contam<strong>in</strong>ationof the 30-day questions, butrather the revised treatment of the lowBIMPUPASAPMAINDIATNWBGURAPUHAKEfrequency items, for which the report<strong>in</strong>gperiod was 30 days <strong>in</strong> the 50th Round <strong>and</strong>365 days <strong>in</strong> the 55th Round. As we havealready noted, the 365-day report<strong>in</strong>g periodfor these items pulls up the lower tailof the consumption distribution, <strong>and</strong> thusbiases down the headcount ratio comparedwith earlier methods. However, Sundaram<strong>and</strong> Tendulkar note that the 50th Roundconta<strong>in</strong>ed both 30-day <strong>and</strong> 365-day report<strong>in</strong>gperiods for the low frequency items.Hence, by recalculat<strong>in</strong>g the 50th Roundheadcounts us<strong>in</strong>g the 365-day responses,they can put the 50th <strong>and</strong> 55th Rounds ona roughly comparable basis. When they dothis, they f<strong>in</strong>d that, <strong>in</strong> both rural <strong>and</strong> urbansectors, they can confirm a little more thanthree-quarters of the official decl<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong> theheadcount ratios between the two rounds[Sundaram <strong>and</strong> Tendulkar 2002:Table III.8]. These calculations are notidentical to our first-step adjustments (seeTable 1a), but they are close enough to<strong>in</strong>spire some confidence that both sets ofresults are <strong>in</strong> the right range.To sum up, the all-<strong>India</strong> poverty <strong>in</strong>dexespresented earlier <strong>in</strong> this paper are broadlyconsistent with <strong>in</strong>dependent evidence fromthe national accounts statistics <strong>and</strong> theemployment-unemployment surveys, aswell as with related <strong>in</strong>formation on agriculturalwages. There is also some congruencebetween the <strong>in</strong>ter-state contrastsemerg<strong>in</strong>g from NSS data <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>dependent<strong>in</strong>formation on state-specific growth rates3738Economic <strong>and</strong> Political Weekly September 7, 2002


Proportionate decl<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong> rural HCR806040200Source: See Figure 4.Figure 5: Wage Growth <strong>and</strong> <strong>Poverty</strong> Decl<strong>in</strong>e, 1993-94 to 1999-2000PU–4 –2 0 2 4 6 8 10Growth rate of real agricultural wageof ‘state domestic product’ <strong>and</strong> real agriculturalwages. The comb<strong>in</strong>ed evidencefrom these different sources is fairly strong,even though each <strong>in</strong>dividual source hassignificant limitations.IIIEconomic <strong>Inequality</strong> <strong>in</strong> theN<strong>in</strong>etiesIII.1 Growth, <strong>Poverty</strong><strong>and</strong> <strong>Inequality</strong>MABIMPWBAPORASIt is possible to th<strong>in</strong>k about povertydecl<strong>in</strong>e, as captured by st<strong>and</strong>ard poverty<strong>in</strong>dexes, <strong>in</strong> terms of two dist<strong>in</strong>ct components:a growth component <strong>and</strong> a distributioncomponent. The growth componentreflects the <strong>in</strong>crease of average percapita expenditure. The distribution componentcaptures any change that may takeplace <strong>in</strong> the distribution of per capita expenditureover households.This decomposition exercise is pursued<strong>in</strong> Table 4, with reference to the headcountratio (very similar results apply to thepoverty-gap <strong>in</strong>dex). The first column repeatsthe headcount ratio for 1993-94from Table 2. The second column (labelled‘derivative with respect to growth’) showsour estimate of the percentage-po<strong>in</strong>t reduction<strong>in</strong> HCR associated with a distribution-neutral,1 per cent <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> APCE<strong>in</strong> the relevant state. To illustrate, <strong>in</strong> ruralAndhra Pradesh a 1 per cent <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong>APCE <strong>in</strong> 1993-94, with no change <strong>in</strong>HAUPINDIARATNKAGUKEdistribution, would have led to a decl<strong>in</strong>eof 0.9 percentage po<strong>in</strong>ts <strong>in</strong> the ruralheadcount ratio. 29 This derivative dependspositively on the fraction of people whoare at or near the poverty l<strong>in</strong>e, which istypically larger <strong>in</strong> the poorer states. Thefigures <strong>in</strong> column 2 vary from –1.27 <strong>in</strong>rural Assam to –0.15 <strong>in</strong> urban Jammu <strong>and</strong>Kashmir. Column 3 reproduces the totalpercentage growth between 1993-94 <strong>and</strong>1999-2000 from Table 3.If we multiply the second column (thederivative with respect to growth) by thethird column (the amount of growth), weget an estimate of the amount of povertyreduction that we would expect from growthalone, <strong>in</strong> the absence of any change <strong>in</strong> theshape of the distribution. This is an approximation,because the derivative is likelyto change as the headcount ratio falls. Incolumn 4, we report a more precise calculation:an estimate of what the headcountratio would have been <strong>in</strong> 1999-2000 if thedistributions of consumption <strong>in</strong> each statewere identical to those <strong>in</strong> 1993-94, but hadbeen shifted upwards by the amount ofgrowth <strong>in</strong> real per capita expenditure thatactually took place. This can be readilycalculated by reduc<strong>in</strong>g the 1993-94 povertyl<strong>in</strong>es by the amount of growth, <strong>and</strong>re-estimat<strong>in</strong>g the headcount ratios fromthese adjusted l<strong>in</strong>es <strong>and</strong> the 1993-94 expendituredata. These hypothetical changescan then be compared with the actualreductions <strong>in</strong> the headcount ratios, shown<strong>in</strong> the f<strong>in</strong>al column. The differencebetween these last two columns is thechange <strong>in</strong> the headcount ratio that is attributableto changes <strong>in</strong> the shape of theconsumption distribution.It is important to note that the last twocolumns are highly correlated. The correlationcoefficients across the states are0.97 (rural) <strong>and</strong> 0.93 (urban), so that growthalone can predict much of the cross-statepattern of reduction <strong>in</strong> HCRs. Nevertheless,the estimates are far from identical. Inparticular, the all-<strong>India</strong> calculations showthat ‘growth alone’ would have reduced thepoverty rate by more than actually happened,imply<strong>in</strong>g that there was an <strong>in</strong>crease<strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>equality that offset some of the effectsof growth, or put differently, that APCEgrowth among the poor was less than theaverage. These <strong>in</strong>equality effects varysomewhat from state to state <strong>and</strong> are muchweaker <strong>in</strong> rural than <strong>in</strong> urban areas. Inurban <strong>India</strong>, <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>equality moderatedthe decl<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong> the headcount ratio <strong>in</strong>all states except Delhi, Maharashtra, <strong>and</strong>Jammu <strong>and</strong> Kashmir. In some cases, suchas urban Kerala <strong>and</strong> Madhya Pradesh, the‘moderat<strong>in</strong>g effect’ is pronounced, withactual rates of reduction only a little over halfthose predicted by the growth <strong>in</strong> the mean.For the urban sector as a whole (the lastrow of the table), the actual decl<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong> theHCR is one <strong>and</strong> a half po<strong>in</strong>ts lower (5.9versus 7.4 per cent) than would have beenthe case had growth been equally distributedwith<strong>in</strong> each state. This estimate, whichis the population-weighted average of thecorrespond<strong>in</strong>g numbers for each state,calculates what would have happened ifeach household <strong>in</strong> each state had experiencedthe average growth for that state. Analternative, <strong>and</strong> equally <strong>in</strong>terest<strong>in</strong>g, counterfactualis what would have happened if,between 1993-94 <strong>and</strong> 1999-2000, eachhousehold <strong>in</strong> the country had experiencedthe countrywide growth rate of 10.9 percent. Such a calculation yields an all-<strong>India</strong>HCR of 21.4 per cent (for rural <strong>and</strong> urbanareas comb<strong>in</strong>ed), compared with an actualall-<strong>India</strong> HCR of 22.7 per cent based onthe 55th Round. In other words, the all-<strong>India</strong> HCR <strong>in</strong> 1999-2000 was 1.3 percentagepo<strong>in</strong>ts higher than it would have been(with the same growth rate of APCE) <strong>in</strong>the absence of any <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>equality.III.2 Aspects of Ris<strong>in</strong>g <strong>Inequality</strong>Three aspects of ris<strong>in</strong>g economic <strong>in</strong>equality<strong>in</strong> the n<strong>in</strong>eties have come up sofar <strong>in</strong> our story. First, we found strongevidence of ‘divergence’ <strong>in</strong> per capitaEconomic <strong>and</strong> Political Weekly September 7, 2002 3739


consumption across states. Second, ourestimates of the growth rates of per capitaexpenditure between 1993-94 <strong>and</strong> 1999-2000 (Table 3) po<strong>in</strong>t to a significant <strong>in</strong>crease<strong>in</strong> rural-urban <strong>in</strong>equalities at the all-<strong>India</strong> level, <strong>and</strong> also <strong>in</strong> most <strong>in</strong>dividualstates. Third, the decomposition exercise<strong>in</strong> the preced<strong>in</strong>g section shows that ris<strong>in</strong>g<strong>in</strong>equality with<strong>in</strong> states, particularly <strong>in</strong> theurban sector, has moderated the effects ofgrowth on poverty reduction.Table 5 provides more systematic evidenceon recent changes <strong>in</strong> consumption<strong>in</strong>equality with<strong>in</strong> each sector of each stateus<strong>in</strong>g two different measures of <strong>in</strong>equality.We show the logarithm of the differenceof the arithmetic <strong>and</strong> geometric means(approximately the fraction by which thearithmetic mean exceeds the geometricmean), as well as the variance of thelogarithm of per capita expenditure.The table shows that the correction forquestionnaire design is critical for underst<strong>and</strong><strong>in</strong>gwhat has been happen<strong>in</strong>g. (Notethat the correction for prices has no effectwith<strong>in</strong> sectors <strong>and</strong> states.) The direct useof the unit record data <strong>in</strong> the 55th Round,with no adjustment, shows a substantialreduction <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>equality with<strong>in</strong> the ruralsectors of most states, with little or no<strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> the urban sectors. With thecorrection, we see that with<strong>in</strong>-state rural<strong>in</strong>equality has not fallen, <strong>and</strong> that therehave been marked <strong>in</strong>creases <strong>in</strong> with<strong>in</strong>-stateurban <strong>in</strong>equality. We suspect that the ma<strong>in</strong>reason why the unadjusted data are somislead<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> this context is the changefrom 30 to 365 days <strong>in</strong> the report<strong>in</strong>g periodfor the low frequency items (durable goods,cloth<strong>in</strong>g <strong>and</strong> footwear, <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>stitutionalmedical <strong>and</strong> educational expenditures). Thelonger report<strong>in</strong>g period actually reducesthe mean expenditures on those items, butbecause a much larger fraction of peoplereport someth<strong>in</strong>g over the longer report<strong>in</strong>gperiod, the bottom tail of the consumptiondistribution is pulled up, <strong>and</strong> both <strong>in</strong>equality<strong>and</strong> poverty are reduced. Whether 365-days are a better or worse report<strong>in</strong>g periodthan 30-days could be argued either way,but the ma<strong>in</strong> po<strong>in</strong>t here is that the 55th <strong>and</strong>50th Rounds are not comparable, <strong>and</strong> thatthe former artificially shows too little<strong>in</strong>equality compared with the latter. Oncethe corrections are made, we see that, <strong>in</strong>addition to <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>equality betweenstates, there has been a marked <strong>in</strong>crease<strong>in</strong> consumption <strong>in</strong>equality with<strong>in</strong> theurban sector of nearly all states.Two further pieces of evidence areworth mention<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> this context. First,our f<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>gs on ris<strong>in</strong>g economic <strong>in</strong>equalitywith<strong>in</strong> the urban sector are consistent withrecent work by Banerjee <strong>and</strong> Piketty (2001),who use <strong>in</strong>come tax records to documentvery large <strong>in</strong>creases <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>come among thevery highest <strong>in</strong>come earners. They showthat, <strong>in</strong> the 1990s, real <strong>in</strong>comes among thetop one per cent of <strong>in</strong>come earners <strong>in</strong>creasedby a half <strong>in</strong> real terms, while thoseof the top 1 per cent of 1 per cent <strong>in</strong>creasedby a factor of three <strong>in</strong> real terms.Second, it is <strong>in</strong>terest<strong>in</strong>g to compare thegrowth rate of real wages for agriculturallabourers with that of public sector salaries.As we saw earlier, real agriculturalwages have grown at 2.5 per cent or so<strong>in</strong> the n<strong>in</strong>eties. Public sector salaries, fortheir part, have grown at almost 5 per centper year dur<strong>in</strong>g the same period. 30 Giventhat public-sector employees tend to bemuch better off than agricultural labourers,this can be taken as an <strong>in</strong>stance of ris<strong>in</strong>geconomic disparities between differentTable 5: <strong>Inequality</strong> Measuresoccupation groups. S<strong>in</strong>ce agriculturallabourers <strong>and</strong> public sector employeestypically reside <strong>in</strong> rural <strong>and</strong> urban areas,respectively, this f<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>g may just beanother side of the co<strong>in</strong> of ris<strong>in</strong>g ruralurb<strong>and</strong>isparities. Even then, it strengthensthe evidence presented earlier onaspects of ris<strong>in</strong>g economic <strong>in</strong>equality <strong>in</strong>the n<strong>in</strong>eties.To sum up, except for the absence ofclear evidence of ris<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>tra-rural <strong>in</strong>equalitywith<strong>in</strong> states, we f<strong>in</strong>d strong <strong>in</strong>dicationsof a pervasive <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> economic<strong>in</strong>equality <strong>in</strong> the n<strong>in</strong>eties. This isa new development <strong>in</strong> the <strong>India</strong>n economy:until 1993-94, the all-<strong>India</strong> G<strong>in</strong>i coefficientsof per capita consumer expenditure<strong>in</strong> rural <strong>and</strong> urban areas were fairly stable. 31Further, it is worth not<strong>in</strong>g that the rate of<strong>in</strong>crease of economic <strong>in</strong>equality <strong>in</strong> then<strong>in</strong>eties is far from negligible. For <strong>in</strong>stance,the compound<strong>in</strong>g of <strong>in</strong>ter-state‘divergence’ <strong>and</strong> ris<strong>in</strong>g rural-urbanlogAM¥logGM aVariance of Logs50th Round 55th Round 55th Round 50th Round 55th Round 55th RoundAdjustedAdjustedAndhra PradeshAssamBiharGujaratHaryanaHimachal PradeshJammu <strong>and</strong> KashmirKarnatakaKeralaMadhya PradeshMaharashtraOrissaPunjabRajasthanTamil NaduUttar PradeshWest BengalAll-<strong>India</strong> Rural0.140.050.080.100.160.130.100.120.150.130.160.100.130.120.160.130.110.140.090.070.070.090.100.100.060.100.140.100.110.100.100.070.140.100.090.110.130.060.080.110.230.140.070.120.160.120.160.120.140.100.150.120.080.140.240.100.160.170.280.220.160.210.260.220.270.180.220.200.270.230.170.230.170.130.130.180.190.170.120.180.240.180.200.180.190.140.230.180.150.210.220.110.160.180.310.240.140.220.270.220.280.210.240.180.240.210.150.24Andhra PradeshAssamBiharGujaratHaryanaHimachal PradeshJammu <strong>and</strong> KashmirKarnatakaKeralaMadhya PradeshMaharashtraOrissaPunjabRajasthanTamil NaduUttar PradeshWest BengalDelhi0.170.130.150.140.130.380.130.160.200.180.210.150.130.140.210.170.190.160.160.170.140.140.160.090.180.170.170.210.140.140.130.270.180.200.170.140.170.140.150.420.120.170.220.180.210.160.140.140.200.190.190.300.250.270.250.240.370.240.310.310.290.400.290.230.250.390.310.340.290.300.300.250.270.290.160.320.320.290.360.260.250.230.340.310.310.330.270.300.260.280.400.210.340.370.330.400.290.250.260.350.340.350.29 0.21 0.30 0.43 0.39 0.46All-<strong>India</strong> Urban 0.19 0.20 0.21 0.34 0.34 0.37All-<strong>India</strong> 0.17 0.18 0.19 0.29 0.29 0.32Note: a AM is the arithmetic mean <strong>and</strong> GM is the geometric mean: the difference <strong>in</strong> their logarithms is themean relative deviation, a measure of <strong>in</strong>equality.3740Economic <strong>and</strong> Political Weekly September 7, 2002


250.0200.0150.0100.050.0Figure 6: Food Intake for Different Per Capita Income Groups, as a Proportion(Per Cent) of Average Intake (1996-97)0.0Cereals <strong>and</strong> millets Fats <strong>and</strong> oils Sugar <strong>and</strong> Jaggery Milk <strong>and</strong> milk productsPer capita <strong>in</strong>come groups (Rs/cap/month) less than 90 90-150150-300 300-600 more than 600Source: Calculated from National Nutrition Monitor<strong>in</strong>g Bureau (1999), Table 6.9. The data relate to ruralareas of eight sample states.disparities produces very sharp contrasts<strong>in</strong> APCE growth between the rural sectorsof the slow-grow<strong>in</strong>g states <strong>and</strong> the urbansectors of the fast-grow<strong>in</strong>g states (Table 3).This is further compounded by the accentuationof <strong>in</strong>tra-urban <strong>in</strong>equality, which isitself quite substantial, bear<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> m<strong>in</strong>dthat the change is measured over a shortperiod of six years (Table 5).It might be argued that a temporary<strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> economic <strong>in</strong>equality is to beexpected <strong>in</strong> a liberalis<strong>in</strong>g economy, <strong>and</strong>that this trend is likely to be short-lived.Proponents of the ‘Kuznets curve’ mayeven expect it to be reversed <strong>in</strong> due course.However, Ch<strong>in</strong>a’s experience of sharp <strong>and</strong>susta<strong>in</strong>ed <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> economic <strong>in</strong>equalityover a period of more than 20 years, aftermarket-oriented economic reforms were<strong>in</strong>itiated <strong>in</strong> the late 1970s, does not <strong>in</strong>spiremuch confidence <strong>in</strong> this prognosis. 32 It is,<strong>in</strong> fact, an important po<strong>in</strong>ter to the possibilityof further accentuation of economicdisparities <strong>in</strong> <strong>India</strong> <strong>in</strong> the near future.IVQualifications <strong>and</strong> ConcernsIV.1 Food ConsumptionThere have been major changes <strong>in</strong> <strong>India</strong>’sfood economy <strong>in</strong> the n<strong>in</strong>eties. The eightieswere a period of healthy growth <strong>in</strong> agriculturaloutput, food production, <strong>and</strong> realagricultural wages. Dur<strong>in</strong>g the n<strong>in</strong>eties,however, productivity <strong>in</strong>creases sloweddown <strong>in</strong> many states. The quantity <strong>in</strong>dexof agricultural production grew at a lame2 per cent per year or so. The growth ofreal agricultural wages slowed down considerably.And cereal production barelykept pace with population growth. 33The virtual stagnation of per capita cerealproduction <strong>in</strong> the n<strong>in</strong>eties has been accompaniedby a gradual switch from net importsto net exports, <strong>and</strong> also by a massiveaccumulation of public stocks. Correspond<strong>in</strong>gly,there has been no <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> estimatedper capita ‘net availability’ of cereals(Table 6). If anyth<strong>in</strong>g, net availabilitydecl<strong>in</strong>ed a little, from a peak of about 450grams per person per day <strong>in</strong> 1990 to 420grams or so at the end of the n<strong>in</strong>eties. Thisis consistent with <strong>in</strong>dependent evidence,from National Sample Survey data, of adecl<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong> per capita cereal consumption<strong>in</strong> the n<strong>in</strong>eties. Between 1993-94 <strong>and</strong> 1999-2000, for <strong>in</strong>stance, average cereal consumptionper capita decl<strong>in</strong>ed from 13.5 kgper month to 12.7 kg per month <strong>in</strong> ruralareas, <strong>and</strong> from 10.6 to 10.4 kg per month<strong>in</strong> urban areas. 34 This comparison isbased on the ‘uncorrected’ 55th Rounddata, <strong>and</strong> the ‘true’ decl<strong>in</strong>e may be largerstill, given the changes <strong>in</strong> questionnairedesign (Section I.1).The reduction of cereal consumption <strong>in</strong>the n<strong>in</strong>eties may seem <strong>in</strong>consistent withthe notion that poverty has decl<strong>in</strong>ed dur<strong>in</strong>gthe same period. Indeed, this pattern hasbeen widely <strong>in</strong>voked as evidence of ‘impoverishment’<strong>in</strong> the n<strong>in</strong>eties. If cereal consumptionis decl<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g, how can povertybe decl<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g?It is worth not<strong>in</strong>g, however, that thedecl<strong>in</strong>e of cereal consumption is not new.A similar decl<strong>in</strong>e took place (accord<strong>in</strong>g toNational Sample Survey data) dur<strong>in</strong>g theseventies <strong>and</strong> eighties, when poverty wascerta<strong>in</strong>ly decl<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g. Hanchate <strong>and</strong> Dyson’s(2000) recent comparison of rural foodconsumption patterns <strong>in</strong> 1973-74 <strong>and</strong>1993-94 sheds some useful light on thismatter. As the authors show, dur<strong>in</strong>g thisperiod per capita cereal consumption <strong>in</strong>rural areas decl<strong>in</strong>ed quite sharply on average(from 15.8 to 13.6 kgs per personper month), but rose among the pooresthouseholds. The decl<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong> the average isdriven by reduced consumption among thehigher expenditure groups. 35The average decl<strong>in</strong>e is unlikely to bedriven by changes <strong>in</strong> relative prices;<strong>in</strong>deed, there has been little change <strong>in</strong> foodprices, relative to other prices, <strong>in</strong> the <strong>in</strong>terven<strong>in</strong>gperiod. Instead, this pattern appearsto reflect a substitution away fromcereals to other food items as <strong>in</strong>comes rise(at least beyond a certa<strong>in</strong> threshold). Theconsumption of ‘superior’ food items suchas vegetables, milk, fruit, fish <strong>and</strong> meat didrise quite sharply over the same period,across all expenditure groups. Seen <strong>in</strong> thislight, the decl<strong>in</strong>e of average cereal consumptionmay not be a matter of concernper se. Indeed, average cereal consumptionis <strong>in</strong>versely related to per capita <strong>in</strong>comeacross countries (e g, it is lower <strong>in</strong>Ch<strong>in</strong>a than <strong>in</strong> <strong>India</strong>, <strong>and</strong> even lower <strong>in</strong> theUnited States), <strong>and</strong> the same applies acrossstates with<strong>in</strong> <strong>India</strong> (e g, cereal consumptionis higher <strong>in</strong> Bihar or Orissa than <strong>in</strong>Punjab or Haryana).Food <strong>in</strong>take data collected by the NationalNutrition Monitor<strong>in</strong>g Bureau(NNMB) shed further light on this issue.Aside from detailed <strong>in</strong>formation on food<strong>in</strong>take, the NNMB surveys <strong>in</strong>clude roughestimates of household <strong>in</strong>comes. These areused <strong>in</strong> Figure 6 to display the relationbetween per-capita <strong>in</strong>come <strong>and</strong> food <strong>in</strong>take,for different types of food. The substitutionfrom cereals towards other fooditems with ris<strong>in</strong>g per-capita <strong>in</strong>come emergesquite clearly. 36 This pattern, if confirmed,would fit quite well with the data on changeover time. 37 It also implies that the decl<strong>in</strong>eof average cereal consumption <strong>in</strong> the n<strong>in</strong>etiesis not <strong>in</strong>consistent with our earlierf<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>gs on poverty decl<strong>in</strong>e. 38IV.2 Localised Impoverishment<strong>and</strong> Hidden CostsThe overall decl<strong>in</strong>e of poverty <strong>in</strong> then<strong>in</strong>eties does not rule out the possibilityof impoverishment among specific regionsor social groups. That possibility, of course,is not new, but it is worth ask<strong>in</strong>g whetherEconomic <strong>and</strong> Political Weekly September 7, 2002 3741


6.05.04.03.02.01.00.0Figure 7:Progress of Selected Social Indicators <strong>in</strong> the 1980s <strong>and</strong> 1990s(Per Cent Per Year)5.52.52.9Increase of real Decl<strong>in</strong>e of <strong>in</strong>fant Decl<strong>in</strong>e of total Decl<strong>in</strong>e ofagricultural wages mortality rate fertility rate illiteracy rateSource: Drèze <strong>and</strong> Sen (2002), chapter 9.1.5its scope has exp<strong>and</strong>ed dur<strong>in</strong>g the lastdecade. As the economy gives greater roomto market forces, uncerta<strong>in</strong>ty <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>equalityoften <strong>in</strong>crease, possibly lead<strong>in</strong>g toenhanced economic <strong>in</strong>security among thosewho are not <strong>in</strong> a position to benefit fromthe new opportunities, or whose livelihoodsare threatened by the changes <strong>in</strong> theeconomy. The <strong>in</strong>crease of economic <strong>in</strong>equality<strong>in</strong> the n<strong>in</strong>eties, noted earlier,suggests that tendencies of this k<strong>in</strong>d maywell be at work <strong>in</strong> <strong>India</strong> today. Adversetrends <strong>in</strong> liv<strong>in</strong>g st<strong>and</strong>ards could take severaldist<strong>in</strong>ct forms, <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g: (1) impoverishmentamong specific regions or socialgroups, (2) heightened uncerta<strong>in</strong>ty <strong>in</strong>general, <strong>and</strong> (3) grow<strong>in</strong>g ‘hidden costs’ ofeconomic development.In connection with the first po<strong>in</strong>t, wehave already noted that some of the poorerstates, notably Orissa <strong>and</strong> Assam, have notfared well at all <strong>in</strong> the n<strong>in</strong>eties. It is quitepossible that the poorer regions with<strong>in</strong>these states have done even worse, to thepo<strong>in</strong>t of absolute impoverishment forsubstantial sections of the population. Inthe case of Orissa, there is some <strong>in</strong>dependentevidence of localised impoverishment<strong>in</strong> the poorer districts, due <strong>in</strong>ter alia to thedestruction of the local environmental base<strong>and</strong> to the dismal failure of state-sponsoreddevelopment programmes [Drèze2001]. 39Similarly, the overall improvement ofliv<strong>in</strong>g st<strong>and</strong>ards may hide <strong>in</strong>stances ofimpoverishment among specific occupationgroups. The n<strong>in</strong>eties have been a periodof rapid structural change <strong>in</strong> the <strong>India</strong>neconomy, lead<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> some cases to1.71.81.52.81980s1990sconsiderable disruption of earlier livelihoodpatterns. Examples <strong>in</strong>clude a deeprecession <strong>in</strong> the powerloom sector, a seriouscrisis <strong>in</strong> the edible oil <strong>in</strong>dustry afterimport tariffs were slashed, periodic wavesof bankruptcy among cotton growers, thedisplacement of traditional fish<strong>in</strong>g bycommercial shrimp farms, <strong>and</strong> a numberof sectoral crises associated with the abruptlift<strong>in</strong>g of quantitative restrictions on imports<strong>in</strong> mid-2001. 40 The destruction oflocal environmental resources is anothercommon cause of disrupted livelihoods <strong>in</strong>many areas.A related issue is the possibility of ‘hiddenhardships’ associated with recent patternsof economic development. To illustrate,there is much evidence that, <strong>in</strong> many ofthe poorer regions of <strong>India</strong>, further impoverishmenthas been avoided ma<strong>in</strong>ly throughseasonal labour migration. 41 The latteroften entails significant social costs thatTable 6: Cereal Availability <strong>in</strong> the N<strong>in</strong>eties(Grams per person per day)are poorly captured, if at all, <strong>in</strong> st<strong>and</strong>ardpoverty <strong>in</strong>dexes or for that matter <strong>in</strong> theother social <strong>in</strong>dicators exam<strong>in</strong>ed <strong>in</strong> thispaper. Examples of such costs <strong>in</strong>cludeirregular school attendance, the spread ofHIV/AIDS, the disruption of family life,<strong>and</strong> ris<strong>in</strong>g urban congestion. 42 Similarly,<strong>in</strong>voluntary displacement of persons affectedby large development projects suchas dams <strong>and</strong> m<strong>in</strong>es tends to have enormoushuman costs. These, aga<strong>in</strong>, are largelyhidden from view <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>come-based analysesof poverty. In fact, the <strong>in</strong>comes ofdisplaced persons often rise (with ‘cashcompensation’) even as their lives are be<strong>in</strong>gshattered. 43 The ‘<strong>in</strong>formalisation’ of labourmarkets is another example of economicchange with substantial hidden costs (e g,longer work<strong>in</strong>g hours, higher <strong>in</strong>security,lower status, <strong>and</strong> deteriorat<strong>in</strong>g work conditions).44 These issues are not new, butit is important to acknowledge the possibilitythat the hidden costs of economicgrowth have <strong>in</strong>tensified <strong>in</strong> the n<strong>in</strong>eties.This acknowledgement helps to reconcilethe survey-based evidence reviewedearlier with widespread media reports, <strong>in</strong>recent years, of sectoral economic crises<strong>and</strong> localised impoverishment. 45 Thisissue calls for further scrut<strong>in</strong>y, based onmore focused analysis of survey data aswell as on micro-studies.IV.3 The ‘Th<strong>in</strong>’ Rounds: AnUnresolved Puzzle?We have so far said very little about the‘th<strong>in</strong>’ rounds, <strong>and</strong> the poverty estimatesthat can be calculated from them. YetFigure 1 shows that the recent th<strong>in</strong> rounds,from the 51st through the 54th Round,generate poverty estimates that are hard toreconcile with the qu<strong>in</strong>quennial ‘thick’rounds. If we were to connect up theseNet Production Net Imports Net Change <strong>in</strong> ‘Net Availability’Public Stocks (1+2-3)1985-89 422.7 2.0 -5.3 430.11990 456.9 0.3 5.0 452.11991 447.9 -1.4 0.4 446.11992 446.8 1.3 4.2 443.81993 446.4 2.5 16.6 432.31994 456.3 0.2 16.6 439.91995 448.6 -5.9 -2.3 445.11996 451.7 -6.9 -11.7 456.41997 445.5 -6.7 -4.2 443.01998 455.3 -4.7 11.0 439.61999 456.3 -5.4 25.3 425.62000 452.7 -5.2 30.7 416.8Note: All figures (except first row) are three-year averages centred at the year specified <strong>in</strong> the first column.Source: Calculated from Government of <strong>India</strong> (2002), p S-21.3742Economic <strong>and</strong> Political Weekly September 7, 2002


po<strong>in</strong>ts with the official HCR estimates, wewould get a series <strong>in</strong> which poverty rosebetween 1993-94 <strong>and</strong> 1994-95, fell from1994-95 to the end of 1997, rose verysharply <strong>in</strong> the first half of 1998, <strong>and</strong> thenfell with extraord<strong>in</strong>ary rapidity <strong>in</strong> 1999-2000. As we have seen, the official estimatefor 1999-2000 is too low, <strong>and</strong> the lastth<strong>in</strong> round, the 54th Round, ran for onlythe first six months of 1998, <strong>and</strong> maytherefore not be fully comparable withother rounds. Even so, <strong>and</strong> with due allowancefor corrections, it is very hard to<strong>in</strong>tegrate the poverty estimates based onthe th<strong>in</strong> rounds with the picture that emergesfrom the thick rounds as well as from othersources surveyed <strong>in</strong> this paper.The story is further complicated by thefact that these th<strong>in</strong> rounds were run <strong>in</strong> twoversions, one of which resembled thest<strong>and</strong>ard questionnaire up to <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>gthe 50th Round, <strong>and</strong> one of which – theexperimental questionnaire – had differentreport<strong>in</strong>g periods for different goods.Headcount ratios based on the experimentalquestionnaire (not shown <strong>in</strong> Figure 1)are lower than those from the st<strong>and</strong>ardquestionnaire, because the experimentalquestionnaire generated higher reports ofper capita expenditure. However, they alsoshow ris<strong>in</strong>g HCRs from the 52nd throughthe 54th Rounds, <strong>and</strong> the <strong>in</strong>crease cont<strong>in</strong>ues<strong>in</strong>to the 55th Round if we use comparablereport<strong>in</strong>g periods from that round.Based on the experimental questionnaire,a case could be made that the all-<strong>India</strong>HCR has been ris<strong>in</strong>g s<strong>in</strong>ce 1995-96 [Sen2000]. As we have seen, there are goodgrounds for distrust<strong>in</strong>g the experimentalquestionnaire <strong>in</strong> the 55th Round, becauseof the juxtaposition of the seven-day recall<strong>and</strong> 30-day recall data for food-pan <strong>and</strong>tobacco. Quite likely, the ‘reconciliationeffect’ (see Section I.1) pulled down theestimates of per capita expenditure fromthe experimental questionnaire, thus exaggerat<strong>in</strong>gpoverty by this count. Even so,if poverty were genu<strong>in</strong>ely fall<strong>in</strong>g, there isno obvious explanation why the experimentalquestionnaire should show a rise<strong>in</strong> poverty from 1995 through 1998.The Plann<strong>in</strong>g Commission has neverendorsed poverty counts from the th<strong>in</strong>rounds. In part, this has been because ofthe smaller sample sizes. The Plann<strong>in</strong>gCommission needs estimates of HCRs, notjust for all-<strong>India</strong>, but for <strong>in</strong>dividual states,<strong>and</strong> the th<strong>in</strong> rounds are not large enough tosupport accurate estimates for some of thesmaller (of the major) states. But <strong>in</strong>adequatesample size generates variance,not bias, <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong> any case, the th<strong>in</strong> roundsample sizes are perfectly adequate togenerate accurate estimates for the all-<strong>India</strong> HCRs. The discrepancies <strong>in</strong> Figure 1cannot be expla<strong>in</strong>ed by <strong>in</strong>adequatesample sizes.There are other differences between thick<strong>and</strong> th<strong>in</strong> rounds. For example, the sampl<strong>in</strong>gframe for the 51st, 53rd, <strong>and</strong> 54thRounds was not the census of population,but the ‘economic’ census. In the populationcensus, each household is asked ifit has a family bus<strong>in</strong>ess or enterprise, <strong>and</strong>only such households are <strong>in</strong>cluded <strong>in</strong> thefirst-stage sampl<strong>in</strong>g from the economiccensus when ‘first-stage units’ are drawnwith probability proportional to size. Thismeans that a village with few or no suchhouseholds has only a small or no chanceof be<strong>in</strong>g selected as a first-stage unit. Evenso, when the team reaches the village, allhouseholds are listed <strong>and</strong> have a chanceof be<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> the sample, so it is unclear thatthis choice of frame makes much difference.Indeed, comparison of various socioeconomic<strong>in</strong>dicators (e g, literacy rates,years of school<strong>in</strong>g, l<strong>and</strong>hold<strong>in</strong>g, or familysize) from the surveys suggests no obviousbreaks between the 51st <strong>and</strong> 53rd Roundson the one h<strong>and</strong>, <strong>and</strong> the 52nd Round(which used the population census) on theother. Conversations with NSS <strong>and</strong> Plann<strong>in</strong>gCommission staff sometimes suggestthat there may be other (non-documented)differences <strong>in</strong> the sampl<strong>in</strong>g structure of theth<strong>in</strong> rounds. Certa<strong>in</strong>ly, a tabulation of thepopulation sizes of the first-stage unitsshows that the 52nd Round conta<strong>in</strong>edrelatively few large units compared withthe 51st, 53rd, 54th, <strong>and</strong> 55th rounds; thisis a different issue from the use of theeconomic rather than population census(both the 52nd <strong>and</strong> 55th Rounds use thelatter), <strong>and</strong> the f<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>g suggests that thefirst-stage units <strong>in</strong> the 52nd Round wereselected differently from other rounds <strong>in</strong>some way that is not documented. Moreover,the measurement of consumption isnot the ma<strong>in</strong> purpose of any of these th<strong>in</strong>rounds, all of which have some otherobjective, so it is possible that consumptionis not so fully or carefully collectedas <strong>in</strong> the qu<strong>in</strong>quennial rounds.In short, there are grounds for scepticismabout the validity of the th<strong>in</strong> rounds forpoverty estimation purposes, <strong>and</strong> this is allthe more so if we remember that aside from<strong>in</strong>dicat<strong>in</strong>g no poverty decl<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong> the laten<strong>in</strong>eties, the th<strong>in</strong> rounds also suggest thataverage per capita expenditure was stagnat<strong>in</strong>gdur<strong>in</strong>g that period – someth<strong>in</strong>g thatis very hard to reconcile with other evidence.Hav<strong>in</strong>g said this, we have not beenable to identify any ‘smok<strong>in</strong>g gun’ thatwould po<strong>in</strong>t to a specific problem with anyof these rounds <strong>and</strong> expla<strong>in</strong> their apparentlyanomalous poverty estimates. Untilthat puzzle is resolved, we see the evidencefrom the th<strong>in</strong> rounds as cast<strong>in</strong>g a shadowof doubt over the <strong>in</strong>terpretation of thepoverty estimates presented earlier <strong>in</strong> thispaper. Perhaps the th<strong>in</strong> rounds <strong>in</strong> the nextfive years will offer some useful clues.VBeyond <strong>Poverty</strong> IndexesThe decl<strong>in</strong>e of poverty <strong>in</strong> the n<strong>in</strong>eties,as captured <strong>in</strong> the <strong>in</strong>dicators exam<strong>in</strong>ed sofar, can be seen as an example of cont<strong>in</strong>uedprogress dur<strong>in</strong>g that period. Whether therate of progress has been faster or slowerthan <strong>in</strong> the eighties is difficult to say, <strong>and</strong>the answer is likely to depend on how therate of progress is measured. There is, atany rate, no obvious pattern of “acceleration”or ‘slowdown’ <strong>in</strong> this respect.It is important to supplement the evidencereviewed so far, which essentiallyrelates to purchas<strong>in</strong>g power, with other<strong>in</strong>dicators of well-be<strong>in</strong>g relat<strong>in</strong>g, for <strong>in</strong>stanceto educational achievements, lifeexpectancy, nutritional levels, crime rates,<strong>and</strong> various aspects of social <strong>in</strong>equality.This broader perspective reveals that socialprogress <strong>in</strong> the n<strong>in</strong>eties has followedvery diverse patterns, rang<strong>in</strong>g from acceleratedprogress <strong>in</strong> some fields to slowdown<strong>and</strong> even regression <strong>in</strong> other respects.The po<strong>in</strong>t is illustrated <strong>in</strong> Figure 7,where simple measures of the progress ofdifferent social <strong>in</strong>dicators <strong>in</strong> the n<strong>in</strong>etiesare compared with the correspond<strong>in</strong>gachievements <strong>in</strong> the eighties.Elementary education provides an <strong>in</strong>terest<strong>in</strong>gexample of accelerated progress <strong>in</strong>the n<strong>in</strong>eties. 46 This trend is evident notonly from census data on literacy rates, butalso from National Family Health Surveydata on school participation. To illustrate,school participation among girls aged 6-14jumped from 59 per cent to 74 per centbetween 1992-93 <strong>and</strong> 1998-99. 47 The regionalpatterns are also <strong>in</strong>structive. It isparticularly <strong>in</strong>terest<strong>in</strong>g to note evidence ofrapid progress <strong>in</strong> Madhya Pradesh <strong>and</strong>Rajasthan, demarcat<strong>in</strong>g them clearly fromBihar <strong>and</strong> Uttar Pradesh, the other twomembers of the so-called BIMARU set. 48There is an important po<strong>in</strong>ter here to therelation between public action <strong>and</strong> socialachievements. Indeed, Madhya PradeshEconomic <strong>and</strong> Political Weekly September 7, 2002 3743


<strong>and</strong> Rajasthan are two states where therehave been many <strong>in</strong>terest<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>itiatives <strong>in</strong>the field of elementary education <strong>in</strong> then<strong>in</strong>eties (on the part of government as wellas non-government <strong>in</strong>stitutions), <strong>in</strong> contrastwith Bihar <strong>and</strong> Uttar Pradesh whereschool<strong>in</strong>g matters cont<strong>in</strong>ue to be highlyneglected. The fact the literacy rates <strong>and</strong>school participation have surged <strong>in</strong> themore ‘active’ states is an encourag<strong>in</strong>g<strong>in</strong>dication of the possibility of effectivepublic <strong>in</strong>tervention <strong>in</strong> this field.Turn<strong>in</strong>g to <strong>in</strong>stances of ‘slowdown’, wehave already referred to the slacken<strong>in</strong>g ofthe growth rate of real agricultural wages<strong>in</strong> the n<strong>in</strong>eties. Another important exampleis the slowdown of <strong>in</strong>fant mortality decl<strong>in</strong>e.Dur<strong>in</strong>g the eighties, <strong>India</strong> achieveda reduction of 30 per cent <strong>in</strong> the <strong>in</strong>fantmortality rate – from 114 deaths per 1,000live births <strong>in</strong> 1980 to 80 per 1,000 <strong>in</strong> 1990.Dur<strong>in</strong>g the n<strong>in</strong>eties, however, the <strong>in</strong>fantmortality rate decl<strong>in</strong>ed by only 12.5 percent – from 80 to 70. 49 In fact, <strong>in</strong> thesecond half of the n<strong>in</strong>eties, <strong>India</strong>’s <strong>in</strong>fantmortality rate has rema<strong>in</strong>ed virtually unchanged.In some states, notably Rajasthan,the <strong>in</strong>fant mortality rate has stagnated foras long as 10 years. These worry<strong>in</strong>g trendshave received astonish<strong>in</strong>gly little attention<strong>in</strong> policy debates, <strong>and</strong> even <strong>in</strong> the debateon ‘poverty <strong>in</strong> the n<strong>in</strong>eties’.F<strong>in</strong>ally, there have also been some areasof ‘regression’ <strong>in</strong> the n<strong>in</strong>eties. The <strong>in</strong>creaseof economic <strong>in</strong>equality, discussedearlier, can be seen <strong>in</strong> those terms. Giventhe adverse social consequences of economic<strong>in</strong>equality (rang<strong>in</strong>g from elitist biases<strong>in</strong> public policy to the re<strong>in</strong>forcement ofother types of <strong>in</strong>equality), this accentuationof economic disparities is not a trivialmatter. Another example of adversedevelopment <strong>in</strong> the n<strong>in</strong>eties is the decl<strong>in</strong>e<strong>in</strong> the female-male ratio among children,from 945 girls per 1,000 boys (<strong>in</strong> the 0-6age group) <strong>in</strong> 1991 to 927 girls per 1,000boys <strong>in</strong> 2001. 50 This decl<strong>in</strong>e appears to bedriven by the spread of prenatal sexdeterm<strong>in</strong>ationtechnology <strong>and</strong> sexselectiveabortion, but this does not meanthat it is a ‘technological’ phenomenon,unrelated to other recent economic <strong>and</strong>social trends. Economic growth, <strong>in</strong> particular,may facilitate the spread of sexselectiveabortion, by mak<strong>in</strong>g the use ofsex-determ<strong>in</strong>ation technology more affordable.In this connection, it is worth not<strong>in</strong>gthat the largest decl<strong>in</strong>es of the female-maleratio among children between 1991 <strong>and</strong>2001 occurred <strong>in</strong> five states (Gujarat,Haryana, Himachal Pradesh, Punjab <strong>and</strong>Delhi) that are relatively well-off economically,<strong>and</strong> have also experienced comparativelyhigh rates of growth of per capitaexpenditure <strong>in</strong> the n<strong>in</strong>eties (Table 3). 51A detailed assessment of the progress ofdevelopment <strong>in</strong>dicators <strong>in</strong> the n<strong>in</strong>eties isbeyond the scope of this paper. However,a few general observations can be madeon the basis of these illustrations. First, asnoted already, poverty is not unidimensional.The poverty <strong>in</strong>dexes used <strong>in</strong> thefirst part of this paper are useful <strong>in</strong>dicatorsof <strong>in</strong>adequate purchas<strong>in</strong>g power, but ontheir own do not do justice to the rangeof deprivations we ought to be concernedwith. Follow<strong>in</strong>g on this, it is important toacknowledge that recent progress <strong>in</strong> elim<strong>in</strong>at<strong>in</strong>gpoverty <strong>and</strong> deprivation has beenquite uneven <strong>in</strong> different fields. The debateon ‘poverty <strong>in</strong> the n<strong>in</strong>eties’ has oftenoverlooked this basic po<strong>in</strong>t.Second, this recognition is also important<strong>in</strong> assess<strong>in</strong>g the relation betweenpoverty decl<strong>in</strong>e <strong>and</strong> economic growth. Asnoted earlier, the decl<strong>in</strong>e of poverty <strong>in</strong> then<strong>in</strong>eties, as captured by conventional <strong>in</strong>dexessuch as the headcount ratio or thepoverty-gap <strong>in</strong>dex, has been overwhelm<strong>in</strong>glydriven by the growth of average percapita expenditure. From this it may seemthat the reduction of poverty is ma<strong>in</strong>ly aquestion of economic growth. However,there is an element of circularity <strong>in</strong> thisargument: if poverty is def<strong>in</strong>ed as lack of<strong>in</strong>come, it is not surpris<strong>in</strong>g that the growthof <strong>in</strong>come plays a key role <strong>in</strong> reduc<strong>in</strong>g it.When the multidimensional nature ofpoverty is acknowledged, this relationappears <strong>in</strong> a different light. To illustrate,consider child mortality as an aspect of thedeprivations associated with poverty. Thereis, of course, a significant (negative) relationbetween child mortality <strong>and</strong> purchas<strong>in</strong>gpower. But child mortality is alsostrongly <strong>in</strong>fluenced by other factors suchas educational levels, fertility rates, publichealth provisions (<strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g clean water<strong>and</strong> vacc<strong>in</strong>ations), <strong>and</strong> various aspects ofgender relations. Look<strong>in</strong>g at <strong>in</strong>ter-statecontrasts <strong>in</strong> <strong>India</strong>, the correlation betweenchild mortality <strong>and</strong> average per capitaexpenditure (or even poverty <strong>in</strong>dexes) isactually quite weak. Other factors, particularlyfemale literacy, are often more important.52 Similar comments apply <strong>in</strong> thecontext of elementary education: the n<strong>in</strong>etieshave demonstrated the possibility ofrapid progress <strong>in</strong> this field through public<strong>in</strong>tervention, with or without rapid economicgrowth. In short, the st<strong>and</strong>ard focuson headcount ratios <strong>and</strong> other expenditurebasedpoverty <strong>in</strong>dexes tends to foster asimplistic view of the relation betweeneconomic growth <strong>and</strong> poverty decl<strong>in</strong>e.Third, it is also <strong>in</strong>terest<strong>in</strong>g to re-exam<strong>in</strong>ethe issue of trends <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>equality, <strong>in</strong> the lightof this broader perspective. As discussed<strong>in</strong> Section III, there is much evidence ofris<strong>in</strong>g economic <strong>in</strong>equality <strong>in</strong> the n<strong>in</strong>eties,<strong>in</strong> the form of a widen<strong>in</strong>g rural-urban gap,enhanced <strong>in</strong>ter-state disparities, <strong>and</strong> alsogrow<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>equality with<strong>in</strong> urban areas <strong>in</strong>most states. What about other types ofsocial <strong>in</strong>equality, <strong>in</strong>volv<strong>in</strong>g other dimensionsof well-be<strong>in</strong>g (e g, educational levelsor life expectancy) <strong>and</strong> other bases ofdisadvantage (e g, gender or caste)? Thedecl<strong>in</strong>e of the female-male ratio amongchildren illustrates the fact that the phenomenonof ris<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>equality <strong>in</strong> the n<strong>in</strong>etiesis not conf<strong>in</strong>ed to st<strong>and</strong>ard economic<strong>in</strong>equalities: ‘natality <strong>in</strong>equality’ betweenmales <strong>and</strong> females is also ris<strong>in</strong>g. 53 But thisis not to say that <strong>in</strong>equality has risen acrossthe board. Even with<strong>in</strong> the field of gender<strong>in</strong>equality, there are changes <strong>in</strong> the otherdirection, such as the emergence of asubstantial gender gap <strong>in</strong> life expectancy<strong>in</strong> favour of women, overturn<strong>in</strong>g <strong>India</strong>’slong history of female disadvantage <strong>in</strong> thisrespect. Similarly, it is <strong>in</strong>terest<strong>in</strong>g to notethat while economic disparities betweenrural <strong>and</strong> urban areas have sharply risen<strong>in</strong> the n<strong>in</strong>eties, there are trends <strong>in</strong> theopposite direction as well. The rural-urbangap <strong>in</strong> life expectancy, for <strong>in</strong>stance, hasdecl<strong>in</strong>ed from 10 years or so <strong>in</strong> the late1970s to seven years or so today, <strong>and</strong> ruralurb<strong>and</strong>ifferentials <strong>in</strong> school participationhave also narrowed. 54 Here aga<strong>in</strong>, thepicture is more diverse (<strong>and</strong> more <strong>in</strong>terest<strong>in</strong>g)than it appears on the basis ofpurchas<strong>in</strong>g-power <strong>in</strong>dicators alone.Fourth, the broad approach explored herecalls for a correspond<strong>in</strong>gly broad read<strong>in</strong>gof the causal <strong>in</strong>fluences underly<strong>in</strong>g theidentified changes. In the debate on ‘poverty<strong>in</strong> the n<strong>in</strong>eties’, there has been atendency not only to view developmenttrends <strong>in</strong> unidimensional terms, but alsoto attribute these trends <strong>in</strong> a somewhatmechanical manner to the economic reforms<strong>in</strong>itiated around 1991. At one endof the spectrum, it has been claimed thatthe last decade has been a period of unprecedentedimprovement <strong>in</strong> liv<strong>in</strong>g st<strong>and</strong>ards,thanks to liberalisation. 55 At theother end, the n<strong>in</strong>eties have been describedas a period of widespread ‘impoverishment’,attributed to liberalisation. 56 Clearly,these read<strong>in</strong>gs fail to do justice to thediversity of recent trends. But <strong>in</strong> addition,3744Economic <strong>and</strong> Political Weekly September 7, 2002


they ignore the diversity of causal <strong>in</strong>fluencesthat have a bear<strong>in</strong>g on these trends.The accelerated progress of elementaryeducation <strong>in</strong> the n<strong>in</strong>eties, for <strong>in</strong>stance, haslittle to do with liberalisation, <strong>and</strong> the sameapplies to the slowdown of <strong>in</strong>fant mortalitydecl<strong>in</strong>e, not to speak of the decl<strong>in</strong>e ofthe female-male ratio among children.Much else than liberalisation has happened<strong>in</strong> the n<strong>in</strong>eties, <strong>and</strong> while issues of economicreform are of course extremelyimportant, so are other aspects of economic<strong>and</strong> social policy.VIConclud<strong>in</strong>g RemarksA number of useful lessons emerge fromthis reexam<strong>in</strong>ation of the evidence onpoverty <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>equality <strong>in</strong> the n<strong>in</strong>eties. First,there is consistent evidence of cont<strong>in</strong>u<strong>in</strong>gpoverty decl<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong> the n<strong>in</strong>eties, <strong>in</strong> terms ofthe ‘headcount ratio’. The extent of thedecl<strong>in</strong>e, however, rema<strong>in</strong>s somewhatuncerta<strong>in</strong> at this time. Given the methodologicalchanges that took place betweenthe 50th <strong>and</strong> 55th Rounds of the NationalSample Survey, the official figures (imply<strong>in</strong>ga decl<strong>in</strong>e from 36 per cent to 26 percent <strong>in</strong> the all-<strong>India</strong> headcount ratio between1993-94 <strong>and</strong> 1999-2000) are, strictlyspeak<strong>in</strong>g, <strong>in</strong>valid. We have discussedalternative estimates, based on comparabledata from the two surveys. As it turns out,these adjusted estimates suggest that alarge part of the poverty decl<strong>in</strong>e associatedwith official figures is ‘real’, rather th<strong>and</strong>riven by methodological changes. Whilefurther corroboration <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>vestigation ofthe adjustment procedure is required, theresults have been supported by one <strong>in</strong>dependentstudy us<strong>in</strong>g an entirely differentmethodology [Sundaram <strong>and</strong> Tendulkar2002]. Further, the adjusted figures fitreasonably well with related evidence fromthe national accounts statistics, the employment-unemploymentsurveys, <strong>and</strong> dataon agricultural wages.Second, we have discussed some importantlimitations of the headcount ratio asan <strong>in</strong>dex of poverty (even with<strong>in</strong> the st<strong>and</strong>ardexpenditure-based approach), <strong>and</strong>argued for wider adoption of alternativepoverty <strong>in</strong>dexes such as the poverty-gap<strong>in</strong>dex. The ma<strong>in</strong> argument for us<strong>in</strong>gheadcount ratios is that they have good‘communication value’, <strong>in</strong> so far as theyare relatively easy to underst<strong>and</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>terpret.However, this transparency is tosome extent deceptive, <strong>and</strong> much cautionis required <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>terpret<strong>in</strong>g poverty trendson the basis of headcount ratios. For thepurpose of the poverty comparisons exam<strong>in</strong>ed<strong>in</strong> this paper, the headcount ratio turnsout to be no less <strong>in</strong>formative than thepoverty-gap <strong>in</strong>dex. Yet it was importantto calculate the PGIs, if only to discoverthat this ref<strong>in</strong>ement does not, after all,make much difference <strong>in</strong> this particularcontext.Third, growth patterns <strong>in</strong> the n<strong>in</strong>eties arecharacterised by major regional imbalances.Broadly speak<strong>in</strong>g, the western <strong>and</strong> southernstates (Andhra Pradesh excluded) havetended to do comparatively well. The lowgrowth states, for their part, form a largecontiguous region <strong>in</strong> the north <strong>and</strong> east.This is a matter of concern, s<strong>in</strong>ce thenorthern <strong>and</strong> eastern regions were poorerto start with. Indeed, National SampleSurvey data suggest a strong pattern of<strong>in</strong>ter-regional ‘divergence’ <strong>in</strong> average percapita expenditure (APCE): states thatstarted off with higher APCE levels alsohad higher growth rates of APCE between1993-94 <strong>and</strong> 1999-2000. In some of thepoorer states, notably Assam <strong>and</strong> Orissa,there has been virtually zero growth ofaverage per capita expenditure (<strong>and</strong> verylittle reduction, if any, <strong>in</strong> rural poverty)between 1993-94 <strong>and</strong> 1999-2000. Theseregional patterns are at least broadly consistentwith <strong>in</strong>dependent estimates of thegrowth rates of state domestic product(SDP).Fourth, the <strong>in</strong>tensification of regionaldisparities is only one aspect of a broaderpattern of <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g economic <strong>in</strong>equality<strong>in</strong> the n<strong>in</strong>eties. Two other aspects are ris<strong>in</strong>grural-urban disparities <strong>in</strong> per capita expenditure,<strong>and</strong> ris<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>equality of per capitaexpenditure with<strong>in</strong> urban areas <strong>in</strong> moststates. Further, the real wages of agriculturallabourers have <strong>in</strong>creased more slowlythan per capita GDP, <strong>and</strong> conversely withpublic sector employees, suggest<strong>in</strong>g some<strong>in</strong>tensification of economic <strong>in</strong>equalitybetween occupation groups.Fifth, we have argued for assess<strong>in</strong>gchanges <strong>in</strong> liv<strong>in</strong>g st<strong>and</strong>ards <strong>in</strong> a broaderperspective, go<strong>in</strong>g beyond the st<strong>and</strong>ardfocus on expenditure-based <strong>in</strong>dicators. Inthat broader perspective, a more diversepicture emerges, with areas of acceleratedprogress <strong>in</strong> the n<strong>in</strong>eties as well as slowdown<strong>in</strong> other fields. For <strong>in</strong>stance, thereis much evidence of rapid progress <strong>in</strong> thefield of elementary education, but the rateof decl<strong>in</strong>e of <strong>in</strong>fant mortality has sloweddown. These <strong>and</strong> related trends deservegreater attention than they have received sofar <strong>in</strong> the debate on ‘poverty <strong>in</strong> the n<strong>in</strong>eties’.Sixth, the case for go<strong>in</strong>g beyond expenditure-based<strong>in</strong>dicators applies also to theassessment of <strong>in</strong>equality. While expenditure-baseddata suggest ris<strong>in</strong>g disparities<strong>in</strong> the n<strong>in</strong>eties, the same need not applyto other social <strong>in</strong>dicators. For <strong>in</strong>stance,while economic disparities between rural<strong>and</strong> urban areas have <strong>in</strong>creased <strong>in</strong> then<strong>in</strong>eties, there has been some narrow<strong>in</strong>gof the rural-urban gap <strong>in</strong> terms of lifeexpectancy <strong>and</strong> school participation.F<strong>in</strong>ally, we have argued aga<strong>in</strong>st read<strong>in</strong>gthese trends simply as evidence of theimpact (positive or negative) of ‘liberalisation’.For one th<strong>in</strong>g, the impact of liberalisationis a ‘counterfactual’ question, <strong>and</strong>much depends on how the alternatives arespecified. For another, much else has happened<strong>in</strong> the n<strong>in</strong>eties, other than liberalisation.The evidence we have reviewed isof much <strong>in</strong>terest <strong>in</strong> its own right, <strong>in</strong>dependentlyof the liberalisation debate. Muchwork rema<strong>in</strong>s to be done <strong>in</strong> terms of identify<strong>in</strong>gthe causal relations underly<strong>in</strong>g thetrends we have identified. EPWNotes[We are grateful to Suresh Tendulkar for helpfulcomments]1 See Datt (1999a), Gupta (1999), Bhalla (2000a,2000b), Deaton <strong>and</strong> Tarozzi (2000), Drèze(2000), Lal, Mohan <strong>and</strong> Natarajan (2001),Nagaraj (2000), Ravallion (2000), Sen (2000),Sundaram <strong>and</strong> Tendulkar (2000, 2001, 2002),Visaria (2000), Sundaram (2001a, 2001b,2001c), Ch<strong>and</strong>rasekhar <strong>and</strong> Ghosh (2002),Datt <strong>and</strong> Ravallion (2002), among others.2 On the first position, see, e g, Bhalla (2000a),Bhagwati (2001), Das (2000). On the otherside, see Mehta (2001), Sa<strong>in</strong>ath (2001a,2001b), Shiva (2001a), among others.3 These estimates build on earlier work by Deaton<strong>and</strong> Tarozzi (2000), Deaton (2001a, 2001b)<strong>and</strong> Tarozzi (2001).4 In the 50th Round, the correlation between thelogarithm of total household per capitaexpenditure <strong>and</strong> the logarithm of per capitaexpenditure on this subset of commodities is0.79 <strong>and</strong> 0.86 <strong>in</strong> the rural <strong>and</strong> urban sectors,respectively.5 More precisely, <strong>and</strong> somewhat less restrictively,we require that the probability of be<strong>in</strong>gpoor, given the amount of a household’sexpenditure on these <strong>in</strong>termediate goods,rema<strong>in</strong>s the same <strong>in</strong> the 55th Round as it was<strong>in</strong> the 50th. We require this on a state by statebasis, one sector at a time, which allows theconditional probability to vary by state <strong>and</strong> bysector.6 In Deaton <strong>and</strong> Tarozzi (2000), it is shown that,between the 43rd <strong>and</strong> 50th Rounds, thecomponent of the CPIAL for the uncovereditems grew somewhat less rapidly than thecomponent for the covered items. In consequence,if we were to supplement our price<strong>in</strong>dexes for uncovered items from the CPIAL,Economic <strong>and</strong> Political Weekly September 7, 2002 3745


the estimated rate of <strong>in</strong>crease of consumerprices would come down, <strong>and</strong> correspond<strong>in</strong>gly,there would be a faster decl<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong> the poverty<strong>in</strong>dexes, at least for the period fall<strong>in</strong>g betweenthese two rounds (i e, 1987-88 to 1993-94).7 The Törnqvist price <strong>in</strong>dex is a weightedgeometric <strong>in</strong>dex with weights that are theaverage of the expenditure shares <strong>in</strong> the base<strong>and</strong> comparison periods. It is a superlative<strong>in</strong>dex <strong>in</strong> the sense of Diewert (1976).8 For further details, see EPW ResearchFoundation (1993). On the conceptual <strong>and</strong>practical problems <strong>in</strong>volved <strong>in</strong> def<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g ‘calorienorms’, see Dasgupta <strong>and</strong> Ray (1990) <strong>and</strong>Osmani (1990), <strong>and</strong> the literature cited there.Note also that, if the calorie norms were tobe reapplied today, they would not generatethe same poverty l<strong>in</strong>es. Updat<strong>in</strong>g calorie-normbased poverty l<strong>in</strong>es for <strong>in</strong>flation does notpreserve their calorie-norm status.9 Similar issues arise, of course, <strong>in</strong> the contextof <strong>in</strong>ter-state comparisons, especially betweenstates (e g, Kerala <strong>and</strong> Uttar Pradesh) withradically different consumption patterns <strong>and</strong>social environments. In both cases, comparisonsof liv<strong>in</strong>g st<strong>and</strong>ards call for supplement<strong>in</strong>gexpenditure data with other types of<strong>in</strong>formation, relat<strong>in</strong>g for <strong>in</strong>stance to publicamenities, health achievements, educationallevels, etc.10 The official l<strong>in</strong>e is actually 115.20. We use115.70 because this is the figure yielded bythe official methodology when the calculationsare based on the unit record data, as opposedto the <strong>in</strong>terpolations used by the Plann<strong>in</strong>gCommission. See notes to Table 2.11 The case of Delhi is h<strong>and</strong>led differently.Because there are few sample households <strong>in</strong>rural Delhi, it is not advisable to use the price<strong>in</strong>dex for rural Delhi as part of the calculations.The poverty l<strong>in</strong>e for urban Delhi is calculatedfrom the all-<strong>India</strong> urban poverty l<strong>in</strong>e bymultiply<strong>in</strong>g it by the price <strong>in</strong>dex for urbanDelhi relative to urban <strong>India</strong>.12 Note that this is not the only way of us<strong>in</strong>g the<strong>in</strong>dexes; another (but only one other) possibilitywould be to update the poverty l<strong>in</strong>e for eachsector of each state by its own <strong>in</strong>flation rate.Because we are deal<strong>in</strong>g with price <strong>in</strong>dexes, notprices, the different alternatives will givedifferent answers.13 More precisely, the poverty-gap <strong>in</strong>dex (PGI)calculates the total shortfall of consumptionbelow the poverty l<strong>in</strong>e, per capita of the totalpopulation, <strong>and</strong> expressed as a percentage ofthe poverty l<strong>in</strong>e: PGI ≡ (1/z)[(Σ (z-y i)/n] wherez is the poverty l<strong>in</strong>e, n is the population size,<strong>and</strong> y iis the consumption level of the ith poorperson.14 The poverty-gap <strong>in</strong>dex, however, reta<strong>in</strong>s onelimitation of the headcount ratio: it is notsensitive to the distribution of per capita expenditurebelow the poverty l<strong>in</strong>e. This limitationis overcome by higher-order members ofthe FGT class, such as the ‘squared povertygap<strong>in</strong>dex’ (SPGI), <strong>and</strong> also by the Sen <strong>in</strong>dex.While we have calculated the SPGI estimates,we conf<strong>in</strong>e ourselves here to the poverty-gap<strong>in</strong>dex, for two reasons. First, it is easier to<strong>in</strong>terpret. Second, SPGIs are highly sensitiveto measurement errors at the bottom of the percapita expenditure scale, <strong>and</strong> their reliabilitycalls for further scrut<strong>in</strong>y.15 See Government of <strong>India</strong> (1993b), p 16.16 In Table 2 <strong>and</strong> elsewhere <strong>in</strong> this paper, theterms ‘Bihar’, ‘Madhya Pradesh’ <strong>and</strong> ‘UttarPradesh’ refer to these states as they existedprior to the formation of Jharkh<strong>and</strong>, Chattisgarh<strong>and</strong> Uttaranchal <strong>in</strong> late 2000.17 In the first sub-period, the estimates suggestsome <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> poverty <strong>in</strong> rural Haryana<strong>and</strong> Himachal Pradesh, <strong>and</strong> also <strong>in</strong> urbanHimachal Pradesh, Punjab <strong>and</strong> Delhi. Thesepatterns, however, should be <strong>in</strong>terpreted withcaution, given the relatively small samplesizes for these states <strong>and</strong> the possibility oftransient fluctuations <strong>in</strong> poverty levels <strong>in</strong>specific years.18 Here <strong>and</strong> elsewhere, it is useful to rememberthat the period between 1993-94 <strong>and</strong> 1999-2000 was one of ‘peak’ economic growthfor the <strong>India</strong>n economy, with per capitaGDP grow<strong>in</strong>g at a healthy 4.4 per cent peryear.19 While the relative growth rates of APCE <strong>in</strong>different states are consistent with thecorrespond<strong>in</strong>g relative growth rates of percapita SDP, the levels of per capita SDP growthtend to be higher than those of APCE growth.We shall return to this issue <strong>in</strong> the next section,with reference to the all-<strong>India</strong> figures.20 On the grow<strong>in</strong>g divergence of per capita SDP<strong>in</strong> the n<strong>in</strong>eties, see also Ahluwalia (2000) <strong>and</strong>Drèze <strong>and</strong> Sen (2002).21 For <strong>in</strong>equality <strong>in</strong>dexes, see Table 5 <strong>in</strong>Section III.22 See particularly Bhalla (2000a), Kulsheshtra<strong>and</strong> Kar (2002), Ravallion (2000), Sen (2000),Sundaram <strong>and</strong> Tendulkar (2001).23 Calculated from Central Statistical Organisation(2001), p xxxii.24 In nom<strong>in</strong>al terms, between 1993-94 <strong>and</strong> 1999-2000, consumer expenditure has been grow<strong>in</strong>gat about 11.5 per cent per year accord<strong>in</strong>g toCSO data, <strong>and</strong> 10 per cent per year accord<strong>in</strong>gto our NSS-based estimates. Both the CSO’simplicit price deflator <strong>and</strong> our Törnqvist <strong>in</strong>dexhave been grow<strong>in</strong>g at 8 per cent per year orso dur<strong>in</strong>g this period. Thus, differences <strong>in</strong>price deflators do not seem to help to resolvethe CSO-NSS discrepancy <strong>in</strong> this case, eventhough price-<strong>in</strong>dex differences may haveplayed a role <strong>in</strong> enhanc<strong>in</strong>g that discrepancy<strong>in</strong> earlier periods (see Sen, 2000).25 The NSS surveys, for their part, almost certa<strong>in</strong>lydisproportionately miss wealthy households atthe very top of the distribution, <strong>and</strong> as Banerjee<strong>and</strong> Piketty (2001) have shown, there has beena marked rise <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>comes among the veryhighest earners. Even so, they show that thetotal amount of these earn<strong>in</strong>gs is not enoughto expla<strong>in</strong> the <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g disparity between theNSS <strong>and</strong> the CSO estimates of consumptionexpenditure.26 For details, see, e g, Acharya (1989).27 See, e g, Jose (1988) <strong>and</strong> Sarmah (2000). Notethat the ‘real wage’ estimates used here ignore<strong>in</strong>ter-state differences <strong>in</strong> price levels.28 See Drèze <strong>and</strong> Sen (2002), p 328; on theslowdown of the growth rate of real agriculturalwages <strong>in</strong> the n<strong>in</strong>eties (compared with theeighties), see also Sarmah (2000, 2001).29 Note that these derivatives are not elasticities<strong>in</strong> the usual sense, <strong>and</strong> are not the same asthe elasticities sometimes quoted, which arethe derivatives of the logarithm of the headcountratio with respect to the logarithm of mean percapita expenditure.30 Calculated from Government of <strong>India</strong> (2002),p S-51. There have been further major <strong>in</strong>creases<strong>in</strong> public sector salaries after 1999-2000, withthe gradual implementation of the recommendationsof the Fifth Pay Commission bymany state governments.31 See Drèze <strong>and</strong> Sen (2002), Statistical Appendix,Table A.6; also Datt (1999a, 1999b).32 On ris<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>come <strong>in</strong>equality <strong>in</strong> Ch<strong>in</strong>a <strong>in</strong> thepost-reform period, see Bramall <strong>and</strong> Jones(1993), Griff<strong>in</strong> <strong>and</strong> Zhao Renwei (1993), YaoShujie (1999), Khan <strong>and</strong> Risk<strong>in</strong> (2001), amongothers.33 On these <strong>and</strong> related trends, see Drèze <strong>and</strong> Sen(2002), chapter 9. On the growth of foodgra<strong>in</strong>production, see Government of <strong>India</strong> (2002),pp S-21 <strong>and</strong> S-22.34 See Shariff <strong>and</strong> Mallick (1999), Table 5, <strong>and</strong>National Sample Survey Organisation (2001),pp A-101 <strong>and</strong> A-134.35 For similar observations based on a comparisonof 1972-73 <strong>and</strong> 1993-94 NSS data, see Rao(2000).36 For further evidence, see also National Instituteof Nutrition (1997). This pattern, sometimesknown as the ‘nutrition transition’, is familiarto nutritionists [Drewnoski 1999]. It is worthnot<strong>in</strong>g that its implications for health are notuncontroversial; some nutrition experts haveapparently “po<strong>in</strong>ted to the beneficial healtheffects of dire poverty, poor diets, <strong>and</strong> strenuousmanual labour”, presumably referr<strong>in</strong>g to thebenefits of a low fat, low sugar, <strong>and</strong> high fibrediet, rather than low quantities. (Drewnoski,1999, p 195).37 Unlike NNMB data, National Sample Surveydata suggest that per capita cereal consumptionrises monotonically with per capita expenditure.The contradiction between nutritionalfood <strong>in</strong>take <strong>and</strong> expenditure surveys is neitheruncommon nor fully understood; for twodifferent <strong>in</strong>terpretations of the <strong>India</strong>n case, seeSubramanian <strong>and</strong> Deaton (1996) <strong>and</strong>Subramanian (2001).38 Also worth not<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> this context is tentativeevidence of recent improvement <strong>in</strong> nutritional<strong>in</strong>dicators based on anthropometricmeasurements. Accord<strong>in</strong>g to NNMB data, theproportion of adults with a low “body mass<strong>in</strong>dex” has decl<strong>in</strong>ed <strong>in</strong> the n<strong>in</strong>eties [seeVaidyanathan 2002]. The National FamilyHealth Surveys also suggest that the proportionof undernourished children has decl<strong>in</strong>edbetween 1992-93 <strong>and</strong> 1998-99 [see InternationalInstitute for Population Sciences 1995:xxxiii, <strong>and</strong> International Institute for PopulationSciences, 2000: 267 <strong>and</strong> 443].39 It should also be noted, however, that Orissawas hit by a devastat<strong>in</strong>g cyclone <strong>in</strong> October1999, around the middle of the 55th Roundsurvey period. The 1999-2000 povertyestimates for Orissa are therefore likely to besomewhat ‘above trend’.40 For <strong>in</strong>sightful case studies of localisedeconomic crises <strong>in</strong> the n<strong>in</strong>eties, see e g, Roy(1999), Breman (2001a), Krishna (2001),Jhabvala <strong>and</strong> S<strong>in</strong>ha (2002), Samal (2002), <strong>and</strong>Dabir-Alai (2002).41 See Rodgers <strong>and</strong> Rodgers (2000), Rogaly etal. (2001), Sharma (2001), Institute for HumanDevelopment (2002), among others.3746Economic <strong>and</strong> Political Weekly September 7, 2002


42 On the other h<strong>and</strong>, labour migration canalso have positive roles, such as facilitat<strong>in</strong>gthe diffusion of knowledge [Maharatna 2001]<strong>and</strong> enabl<strong>in</strong>g the disadvantaged castes to“escape from the clutches of the prevail<strong>in</strong>gcaste discrim<strong>in</strong>ation <strong>in</strong> the village” [Sharma2001: 18].43 For a tell<strong>in</strong>g case study of the human costsof <strong>in</strong>voluntary displacement, see Bhatia (1997).44 On this, see particularly Breman (2001a,2001b).45 See e g, Sa<strong>in</strong>ath (2001a, 2001b, 2001c, 2001d),Breman (2001b), Drèze (2001), Mehta (2001).We are not referr<strong>in</strong>g here to media reports ofshort-term hardship associated with the recentdrought (<strong>in</strong> 2000 <strong>and</strong> 2001), but to stories ofsusta<strong>in</strong>ed impoverishment.46 For further discussion, see Drèze <strong>and</strong> Sen(2002), chapter 5.47 See Drèze <strong>and</strong> Sen (2002), p 148; alsoInternational Institute for Population Sciences(1995, 2000), for further details.48 To illustrate, look<strong>in</strong>g at the percentagereduction <strong>in</strong> illiteracy between 1991 <strong>and</strong> 2001,Madhya Pradesh <strong>and</strong> Rajasthan did better thanany other major state except Himachal Pradesh;Uttar Pradesh is very close to the all-<strong>India</strong>average; <strong>and</strong> Bihar ranks second from thebottom (calculated from census data given <strong>in</strong>Government of <strong>India</strong>, 2001b). The comparisonis particularly <strong>in</strong>structive because all fourBIMARU states started off with similar (verylow) levels of literacy <strong>in</strong> 1991. On the ‘school<strong>in</strong>grevolution’ <strong>in</strong> Himachal Pradesh (an even moreremarkable example of successful promotionof elementary education), see PROBE Team(1999), chapter 9.49 See Government of <strong>India</strong> (1999a), Table 1,<strong>and</strong> Sample Registration Bullet<strong>in</strong>, April 2001;also UNICEF (2001) <strong>and</strong> Mari Bhat (2002).The comparison with Bangladesh is also<strong>in</strong>structive: Bangladesh’s <strong>in</strong>fant mortality ratewas much higher than <strong>India</strong>’s <strong>in</strong> 1990 (91 <strong>and</strong>80 per 1,000, respectively), but by 1999 it hadcome down to 61 as aga<strong>in</strong>st <strong>India</strong>’s 71. SeeWorld Development Indicators 2001, pp 16-17.50 On this <strong>and</strong> related issues, see Drèze <strong>and</strong> Sen(2002), chapter 7.51 The relevant female-male ratios are given <strong>in</strong>Government of <strong>India</strong> (2001b), pp 92-94.52 Across states, the correlation coefficient betweenchild mortality <strong>and</strong> per capita expenditureis 0.4 (<strong>in</strong> absolute value), compared with 0.8for the correlation coefficient between childmortality <strong>and</strong> female literacy. After controll<strong>in</strong>gfor female literacy, per capita expenditurebears no significant association with childmortality at the state level. For further discussion,see Drèze <strong>and</strong> Sen (2002), pp 87-89.On the determ<strong>in</strong>ants of mortality <strong>and</strong> fertility<strong>in</strong> <strong>India</strong>, see also Murthi, Guio <strong>and</strong> Drèze(1995) <strong>and</strong> Drèze <strong>and</strong> Murthi (2001), <strong>and</strong>further studies cited there.53 On ‘natality <strong>in</strong>equality’ <strong>and</strong> its significance,see Sen (2001).54 See e g, Government of <strong>India</strong> (1999), p 16,<strong>and</strong> Drèze <strong>and</strong> Sen (2002), p 148.55 To illustrate: “Economic reforms <strong>in</strong>itiated <strong>in</strong>1991 have led to a radical transformation <strong>in</strong>the well-be<strong>in</strong>g of the bottom half of the population.From an approximate level of 38 per cent<strong>in</strong> 1987, poverty level <strong>in</strong> <strong>India</strong> <strong>in</strong> 1998 wasclose to 12 per cent” [Bhalla 2000b, p 7].56 To illustrate: “Both under the World Bankstructural adjustment, <strong>and</strong> from the f<strong>in</strong>ancem<strong>in</strong>istry – it’s feet might be <strong>in</strong> <strong>India</strong>, but it’shead is <strong>in</strong> Wash<strong>in</strong>gton – <strong>and</strong> then under theWorld Trade Organisation obligations, we’rebasically gett<strong>in</strong>g a fundamental destruction ofnotions of the rights of citizens… Very vitalresources we need both for survival – dr<strong>in</strong>k<strong>in</strong>gwater, all the resources people need forlivelihoods – are just disappear<strong>in</strong>g so rapidlythat life is becom<strong>in</strong>g impossible…we reallyhave a very, very major crisis of survival ath<strong>and</strong>....” [Shiva 2001b]. For further contributionson both sides of the debate, see theliterature cited <strong>in</strong> footnote 2.ReferencesAcharya, Sarthi (1989): ‘Agricultural Wages <strong>in</strong><strong>India</strong>: A Disaggregated Analysis’, <strong>India</strong>nJournal of Agricultural Economics, 44.Ahluwalia, Montek S (2000): ‘EconomicPerformance of States <strong>in</strong> Post-reforms Period’,Economic <strong>and</strong> Political Weekly, May 6.Banerjee, A <strong>and</strong> Piketty, T (2001): ‘Are the RichGrow<strong>in</strong>g Richer: Evidence from <strong>India</strong>n TaxData’, MIT, Cambridge MA, <strong>and</strong> CEPREMAP,Paris, processed. Available at http://www.worldbank.org/<strong>in</strong>diapovertyworkshop.Bhagwati, Jagdish (2001): ‘Growth, <strong>Poverty</strong> <strong>and</strong>Reforms’, Economic <strong>and</strong> Political Weekly,March 10.Bhalla, Surjit (2000a): ‘Growth <strong>and</strong> <strong>Poverty</strong> <strong>in</strong><strong>India</strong>: Myth <strong>and</strong> Reality’, mimeo, OxusResearch <strong>and</strong> Investments, New Delhi.– (2000b): ‘FAQ’s on <strong>Poverty</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>India</strong>’, mimeo,Oxus Research <strong>and</strong> Investments, New Delhi.Bhatia, Bela (1997): ‘Forced Evictions <strong>in</strong> theNarmada Valley’ <strong>in</strong> Drèze, J P , Samson, M,<strong>and</strong> S<strong>in</strong>gh, S (eds) (1997), The Dam <strong>and</strong> theNation: Displacement <strong>and</strong> Resettlement <strong>in</strong> theNarmada Valley, Oxford <strong>University</strong> Press,New Delhi.Bramall, Chris, <strong>and</strong> Jones, Marion (1993): ‘RuralIncome <strong>Inequality</strong> <strong>in</strong> Ch<strong>in</strong>a s<strong>in</strong>ce 1978’,Journal of Peasant Studies, 21(1).Breman, Jan (2001a): ‘An Informalised LabourSystem: End of Labour Market Dualism’,Economic <strong>and</strong> Political Weekly, 35(52).– (2001b): ‘The State of <strong>Poverty</strong> <strong>in</strong> Urban <strong>India</strong>at the Beg<strong>in</strong>n<strong>in</strong>g of the 21st Century’,Sukhamoy Chakravarty Memorial Lecture,Delhi School of Economics, November 16.Central Statistical Organisation (2001): NationalAccounts Statistics 2001, CSO, New Delhi.Ch<strong>and</strong>rasekhar, C P, <strong>and</strong> Ghosh, J (2002): TheMarket that Failed: A Decade of NeoliberalEconomic Reforms <strong>in</strong> <strong>India</strong>, Leftword Books,New Delhi.Dabir-Alai, Parviz (2002): ‘The Socio-Economicsof Street Vend<strong>in</strong>g: A Case Study ofVulnerability for Delhi <strong>in</strong> the 1990s’, mimeo,Richmond School of Bus<strong>in</strong>ess, London.Das, Gurcharan (2000): <strong>India</strong> Unbound, Pengu<strong>in</strong>,New Delhi.Dasgupta, Partha, <strong>and</strong> Ray, Debraj (1990):‘Adapt<strong>in</strong>g to Undernourishment: TheBiological Evidence <strong>and</strong> Its Implications’ <strong>in</strong>Drèze <strong>and</strong> Sen (1990), vol i.Datt, Gaurav (1999a): ‘Has <strong>Poverty</strong> Decl<strong>in</strong>ed s<strong>in</strong>ceEconomic Reforms?’, Economic <strong>and</strong> PoliticalWeekly, December 11-17.– (1999b): ‘<strong>Poverty</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>India</strong>: Trends <strong>and</strong> Decompositions’,mimeo, World Bank, Wash<strong>in</strong>gton,DC.Datt, Gaurav, <strong>and</strong> Ravallion, Mart<strong>in</strong> (2002): ‘Is<strong>India</strong>’s Economic Growth Leav<strong>in</strong>g the PoorBeh<strong>in</strong>d?’, mimeo, World Bank, Wash<strong>in</strong>gton,DC.Deaton, Angus (2001a): ‘Adjusted <strong>India</strong>n <strong>Poverty</strong>Estimates for 1999-2000’, Pr<strong>in</strong>ceton, ResearchProgramme <strong>in</strong> Development Studies, processed.Available at http://www.wws.pr<strong>in</strong>ceton.edu/~rpds.– (2001b): ‘Comput<strong>in</strong>g Prices <strong>and</strong> <strong>Poverty</strong> Rates<strong>in</strong> <strong>India</strong>, 1999-2000’, Pr<strong>in</strong>ceton, ResearchProgramme <strong>in</strong> Development Studies, processed.Available at http://www.wws.pr<strong>in</strong>ceton.edu/~rpds.Deaton, Angus <strong>and</strong> Tarozzi, Aless<strong>and</strong>ro (2000):‘Prices <strong>and</strong> <strong>Poverty</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>India</strong>’, Pr<strong>in</strong>ceton, ResearchProgramme <strong>in</strong> Development Studies,processed. Available at http://www.wws.pr<strong>in</strong>ceton.edu/~rpds.Diewert, W Erw<strong>in</strong> (1976): ‘Exact <strong>and</strong> SuperlativeIndex Numbers’, Journal of Econometrics, 4.Drewnowski, Adam (1999): ‘Fat <strong>and</strong> Sugar <strong>in</strong> theGlobal Diet: Dietary Diversity <strong>in</strong> the NutritionTransition’ <strong>in</strong> Grew, R (ed), Food <strong>in</strong> GlobalHistory, Westview, Boulder.Drèze, Jean (2000): ‘<strong>Poverty</strong>: Beyond HeadcountRatios’, The H<strong>in</strong>du, September 9.– (2001): ‘No More Lifel<strong>in</strong>es: Political Economyof Hunger <strong>in</strong> Orissa’, The Times of <strong>India</strong>,September, 17.Drèze, Jean, <strong>and</strong> Murthi, Mamta (2001): ‘Fertility,Education, <strong>and</strong> Development: Evidence from<strong>India</strong>’, Population <strong>and</strong> Development Review,27.Drèze, Jean <strong>and</strong> Sen, Amartya (eds) (1990): ThePolitical Economy of Hunger, Clarendon,Oxford.– (2002): <strong>India</strong>: Development <strong>and</strong> ParticipationOxford <strong>University</strong> Press, New Delhi.EPW Research Foundation (1993): ‘<strong>Poverty</strong> Levels<strong>in</strong> <strong>India</strong>: Norms, Estimates <strong>and</strong> Trends’,Economic <strong>and</strong> Political Weekly, August 21.Government of <strong>India</strong> (1993a): Report of the ExpertGroup on Estimation of Proportion <strong>and</strong>Number of Poor, Plann<strong>in</strong>g Commission, NewDelhi.– (1993b): Sample Registration System: Fertility<strong>and</strong> Mortality Indicators 1990, Office of theRegistrar General, New Delhi.– (1999): Compendium of <strong>India</strong>’s Fertility <strong>and</strong>Mortality Indicators 1971-1997, Office of theRegistrar General, New Delhi.– (2001a): Economic Survey 2000-2001, M<strong>in</strong>istryof F<strong>in</strong>ance, New Delhi.– (2001b): ‘Provisional Population Totals’, Censusof <strong>India</strong> 2001, Series 1(<strong>India</strong>), Paper 1 of 2001,Office of the Registrar General, New Delhi.–(2002): Economic Survey 2001-2002, M<strong>in</strong>istryof F<strong>in</strong>ance, New Delhi.Griff<strong>in</strong>, K, <strong>and</strong> Zhao Renwei (eds) (1993): TheDistribution of Income <strong>in</strong> Ch<strong>in</strong>a, Macmillan,London.Gupta, S P (1999): ‘Tricle Down Theory Revisited:The Role of Employment <strong>and</strong> <strong>Poverty</strong>’, V BS<strong>in</strong>gh Memorial Lecture, 41st Annual Conferenceof the <strong>India</strong>n Society of LabourEconomics, November 18-20, Mumbai.Hanchate, A <strong>and</strong> Dyson, T (2000): ‘Trends <strong>in</strong> theComposition of Food Consumption <strong>and</strong> theirImpact on Nutrition <strong>and</strong> <strong>Poverty</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>India</strong>’,mimeo, London School of Economics.Economic <strong>and</strong> Political Weekly September 7, 2002 3747


Institute for Human Development (2002):‘Dynamics of <strong>Poverty</strong>, Employment <strong>and</strong>Human Development <strong>in</strong> Bihar’, project report;to be published as a monograph.International Institute for Population Sciences(1995): National Family Health Survey1992-93: <strong>India</strong>, IIPS, Mumbai.– (2000): National Family Health Survey 1998-99(NFHS-2): <strong>India</strong>, IIPS, Mumbai.Jhabvala, R <strong>and</strong> S<strong>in</strong>ha, S (2002): ‘Liberalisation<strong>and</strong> the Woman Worker’, Economic <strong>and</strong>Political Weekly, May 25.Jose, A V (1988): ‘Agricultural Wages <strong>in</strong> <strong>India</strong>’,Economic <strong>and</strong> Political Weekly, June, 25.Khan, A R <strong>and</strong> Risk<strong>in</strong>, C (2001): <strong>Inequality</strong> <strong>and</strong><strong>Poverty</strong> <strong>in</strong> Ch<strong>in</strong>a <strong>in</strong> the Age of Globalisation,Oxford <strong>University</strong> Press, New York.Krishna, Sridhar (2001): ‘Phas<strong>in</strong>g Out of ImportLicens<strong>in</strong>g: Impact on Small-scale Industries’,Economic <strong>and</strong> Political Weekly, July 7.Kulshreshtha, A C <strong>and</strong> Kar, A (2002): ‘Estimatesof Food Consumption Expenditure fromHousehold Surveys <strong>and</strong> National Accounts’,paper presented at the jo<strong>in</strong>t Plann<strong>in</strong>g Commission/WorldBank workshop on povertymeasurement, Delhi, January. Available athttp://www.worldbank.org/<strong>in</strong>diapovertyworkshop.Lal, D, Mohan, R <strong>and</strong> Natarajan, I (2001):‘Economic Reforms <strong>and</strong> <strong>Poverty</strong> Alleviation:A Tale of Two Surveys’, Economic <strong>and</strong>Political Weekly, March, 24.Maharatna, Arup (2001): ‘On the ‘Brighter Side’of Seasonal Migration: A Case Study of FertilityTransition <strong>in</strong> Tribal Population <strong>in</strong> RuralWest Bengal, <strong>India</strong>’, mimeo, Gokhale Instituteof Politics <strong>and</strong> Economics, Pune.Mari Bhat, P N (2002): ‘Has the Decl<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong> InfantMortality Rate Slowed Down? A Review ofSRS Evidence’, paper presented at a nationalworkshop on ‘Infant Mortality: Levels, Trends<strong>and</strong> Interventions’ held at New Delhi onApril 11-12.Mehta, Jaya (2001): ‘Give <strong>Poverty</strong> a Face Please!’,<strong>in</strong> Alternative Economic Survey 2000-2001,Ra<strong>in</strong>bow Publishers, Delhi.Murthi, M, Guio, A C <strong>and</strong> Drèze, J P (1995):‘Mortality, Fertility <strong>and</strong> Gender Bias <strong>in</strong> <strong>India</strong>’,Population <strong>and</strong> Development Review, 21.Nagaraj, R (2000): ‘<strong>India</strong>n Economy s<strong>in</strong>ce 1980:Virtuous Growth or Polarisation?’, Economic<strong>and</strong> Political Weekly, August 5.National Institute of Nutrition (1997): 25 Yearsof National Nutrition Monitor<strong>in</strong>g Bureau, NIN,Hyderabad.National Nutrition Monitor<strong>in</strong>g Bureau (1999):Report of Second Repeat Survey – Rural(1996- 97), National Institute of Nutrition,Hyderabad.National Sample Survey Organisation (2001a):‘Level <strong>and</strong> Pattern of Consumer Expenditure<strong>in</strong> <strong>India</strong> 1999-2000’, Report 457, NationalSample Survey Organisation, New Delhi.– (2001b): ‘Consumption of Some ImportantCommodities”, Report 461, National SampleSurvey Organisation, New Delhi.Osmani, Siddiq R (1990): ‘Nutrition <strong>and</strong> theEconomics of Food: Implications of SomeRecent Controversies’ <strong>in</strong> Drèze <strong>and</strong> Sen (1990),vol i.PROBE Team (1999): Public Report onBasic Education <strong>in</strong> <strong>India</strong>, Oxford <strong>University</strong>Press, New Delhi.Rao, C H Hanumantha (2000): ‘Decl<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g Dem<strong>and</strong>for Foodgra<strong>in</strong>s <strong>in</strong> Rural <strong>India</strong>: Causes <strong>and</strong>Implications’, Economic <strong>and</strong> Political Weekly,January 22.Ravallion, Mart<strong>in</strong> (2000): ‘Should <strong>Poverty</strong>Measures be Anchored to the NationalAccounts?’, mimeo, ARQADE, <strong>University</strong> ofToulouse.Rodgers, Gerry <strong>and</strong> Rodgers, Jan<strong>in</strong>e (2000): ‘Semi-Feudalism Meets the Market: A Report fromPurnia’, Work<strong>in</strong>g Paper 6, Institute for HumanDevelopment, New Delhi.Rogaly, B, Biswas, J, Coppard, D, Rafique,A, Rana, K <strong>and</strong> Sengupta, A (2001): ‘SeasonalMigration, Social Change <strong>and</strong> Migrants’ Rights:Lessons from West Bengal’, Economic <strong>and</strong>Political Weekly, December 8.Roy, Tirthankar (1999): ‘Growth <strong>and</strong> Recession<strong>in</strong> Small-Scale Industry: A Study of TamilNadu Powerlooms’, Economic <strong>and</strong> PoliticalWeekly, October 30.Sa<strong>in</strong>ath, P (2001a): ‘Will the Real NationalCalamity Please St<strong>and</strong> Up?’, The H<strong>in</strong>du,February 25.– (2001b): ‘It’s the Policy, Stupid, Not Implementation’(2 parts), The H<strong>in</strong>du, September.– (2001c): ‘Mass Media: Disconnected from MassReality’, The H<strong>in</strong>du, September 2.– (2001d): ‘Where Stomachaches Are Term<strong>in</strong>al’,The H<strong>in</strong>du, April 29.Samal, K C (2002): ‘Shrimp Culture <strong>in</strong> ChilikaLake: Case of Occupational Displacement ofFishermen’, Economic <strong>and</strong> Political Weekly,May 4.Sarmah, Sasanka (2000): ‘Agricultural Wages:Trends <strong>and</strong> Determ<strong>in</strong>ants’, M Phil thesis, DelhiSchool of Economics.– (2001): ‘Agricultural Wages <strong>in</strong> <strong>India</strong>: An Analysisof Regions <strong>and</strong> States’, mimeo, Centre forDevelopment Economics at the Delhi Schoolof Economics; forthcom<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> <strong>India</strong>n Journalof Labour Economics.Sen, Abhijit (2000): ‘Estimates of ConsumerExpenditure <strong>and</strong> its Distribution’, Economic<strong>and</strong> Political Weekly, December 16.Sen, Amartya (2001): ‘Many Faces of Gender<strong>Inequality</strong>’, Frontl<strong>in</strong>e, October 27, 2001.Shariff, A <strong>and</strong> Mallick, A C (1999): ‘Dynamicsof Food Intake <strong>and</strong> Nutrition by ExpenditureClass <strong>in</strong> <strong>India</strong>’, Economic <strong>and</strong> Political Weekly,July 3.Sharma, Alakh (2001): ‘Agrarian Relations <strong>and</strong>Socio-Economic Change <strong>in</strong> Bihar’, paperpresented at a conference on ‘Labour <strong>and</strong>Capitalist Transformation <strong>in</strong> Asia’ held at theCentre for Development Studies, Thiruvananthapuram,December 13-15.Shiva, V<strong>and</strong>ana (2001a): ‘<strong>India</strong>: Corporatisationof Agriculture Disastrous’, The Guardian,March 7.–(2001b): ‘Is Globalisation Kill<strong>in</strong>g the Environment?’,<strong>in</strong>terview with Frederick Noronha;available at http://www.onweb.org/archive/features/shiva/shiva.html.Subramanian, A (2001): ‘Are Income-CalorieElasticities Really High <strong>in</strong> Develop<strong>in</strong>gCountries? Some Implications for Nutrition<strong>and</strong> Income’, mimeo, National Council ofApplied Economic Research, New Delhi.Subramanian, Shankar <strong>and</strong> Angus Deaton (1996):‘The Dem<strong>and</strong> for Food <strong>and</strong> Calories’, Journalof Political Economy, 104, 133-62.Sundaram, K (2001a): ‘Employment-Unemployment Situation <strong>in</strong> N<strong>in</strong>eties: SomeResults from NSS 55th Round Survey’,Economic <strong>and</strong> Political Weekly, March, 17.– (2001b): ‘Employment <strong>and</strong> <strong>Poverty</strong> <strong>in</strong> 1990s:Further Results from NSS 55th RoundEmployment-Unemployment Survey, 1999-2000’, Economic <strong>and</strong> Political Weekly,August 11.– (2001c): ‘<strong>Poverty</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>India</strong>: Some Issues <strong>in</strong>Measurement <strong>and</strong> Database’, mimeo, DelhiSchool of Economics, Delhi.Sundaram, K <strong>and</strong> Tendulkar, S (2000): ‘<strong>Poverty</strong><strong>in</strong> <strong>India</strong>: An Assessment <strong>and</strong> Analysis’, draftreport for the Asia Development Bank; mimeo,Delhi School of Economics, Delhi.– (2001): ‘NAS-NSS Estimates of PrivateConsumption for <strong>Poverty</strong> Estimation: A DisaggregatedComparison for 1993-94’,Economic <strong>and</strong> Political Weekly, January 13.– (2002): ‘Recent Debates on Data Base forMeasurement of <strong>Poverty</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>India</strong>’, DelhiSchool of Economics, processed. Presented atjo<strong>in</strong>t GOI/World Bank poverty workshop,Delhi, January 2002. Available at http://www.worldbank.org/<strong>in</strong>diapovertyworkshop.Tarozzi, Aless<strong>and</strong>ro (2001): ‘Estimat<strong>in</strong>g Comparable<strong>Poverty</strong> Counts from IncomparableSurveys: Measur<strong>in</strong>g <strong>Poverty</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>India</strong>’, ResearchProgramme <strong>in</strong> Development Studies, Pr<strong>in</strong>ceton<strong>University</strong>, processed. Available at http://www.wws.pr<strong>in</strong>ceton.edu/~rpds.UNICEF (2001): ‘GOI-UNICEF CountryProgramme of Cooperation 2003-2007’,mimeo, UNICEF, New Delhi.Vaidyanathan, A (2002): ‘Food Consumption <strong>and</strong>Nutrition Status: A Re-exam<strong>in</strong>ation Based on<strong>India</strong>n Evidence’, mimeo, Madras Institute ofDevelopment Studies, Chennai.Visaria, Prav<strong>in</strong> (2000): ‘Alternative Estimatesof <strong>Poverty</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>India</strong>’, The Economic Times,June 27.Yao Shujie (1999): ‘Economic Growth, Income<strong>Inequality</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>Poverty</strong> <strong>in</strong> Ch<strong>in</strong>a underEconomic Reforms’, Journal of DevelopmentStudies, 35.3748Economic <strong>and</strong> Political Weekly September 7, 2002

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!