12.07.2015 Views

Acting in the public interest – a framework for analysis - ICAEW

Acting in the public interest – a framework for analysis - ICAEW

Acting in the public interest – a framework for analysis - ICAEW

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS
  • No tags were found...

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

<strong>ICAEW</strong>, as part of a campaign <strong>for</strong> better regulation, commissioned a review of economicliterature on regulation, which noted a number of concerns about <strong>the</strong> effects of regulationon economic efficiency. 67 This highlights <strong>the</strong> need <strong>for</strong> safeguards such as impact <strong>analysis</strong>,engagement with relevant people and on-go<strong>in</strong>g monitor<strong>in</strong>g and evaluation.3.4 Safeguards3.4.1 Impact <strong>analysis</strong>One method of assess<strong>in</strong>g that all relevant factors have been weighed up, and demonstrat<strong>in</strong>gthat this has been done, is impact <strong>analysis</strong> (or effects <strong>analysis</strong> 68 ), of which a subset is also knownas cost benefit <strong>analysis</strong>. Governments and o<strong>the</strong>r regulators seek <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>gly to apply this whenconsider<strong>in</strong>g changes <strong>in</strong> laws and regulations. It is not a recent phenomenon, cropp<strong>in</strong>g up <strong>for</strong>example <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> US Flood Control Act of 1936 which asserted a responsibility to act where ‘<strong>the</strong>benefits to whomsoever <strong>the</strong>y may accrue are <strong>in</strong> excess of <strong>the</strong> estimated costs…’ 69It is <strong>in</strong> pr<strong>in</strong>ciple a variant on utility <strong>the</strong>ory, follow<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> same logic of assess<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> positive ornegative value of an action to those affected. It <strong>the</strong>re<strong>for</strong>e suffers many of <strong>the</strong> same problems,<strong>for</strong> example:• <strong>the</strong> tendency to quantify disregards or pays <strong>in</strong>sufficient attention to effects whosemagnitude is not well understood and overemphasises effects more readily expressed <strong>in</strong>monetary amounts; and• cost quantification is often provided by those responsible <strong>for</strong> implementation, who<strong>the</strong>re<strong>for</strong>e have an <strong>in</strong>terest <strong>in</strong> exaggerat<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> costs. 70The scope of what can be <strong>in</strong>cluded <strong>in</strong> costs and benefits (<strong>for</strong> example <strong>the</strong> extent to which<strong>in</strong>direct costs and benefits should be <strong>in</strong>cluded) is also susceptible to be<strong>in</strong>g eng<strong>in</strong>eered,depend<strong>in</strong>g on whe<strong>the</strong>r those per<strong>for</strong>m<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> assessment are subjectively supportive of, oropposed to, <strong>the</strong> measure. 71Panel 3.3: Cont<strong>in</strong>gent valuation modelSome of <strong>the</strong> issues described above can be dealt with by us<strong>in</strong>g a cont<strong>in</strong>gent valuation model(CVM). Such models ask about people’s will<strong>in</strong>gness to pay <strong>for</strong>, or will<strong>in</strong>gness to accept, aproposed measure, ‘cont<strong>in</strong>gent’ on <strong>the</strong>ir be<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> real situation. Thus, <strong>for</strong> example, <strong>the</strong>results to <strong>the</strong> question ‘how much would you pay to receive a certa<strong>in</strong> non-monetary benefit?’can quantify people’s perception, at least, of <strong>the</strong> value of that benefit.CVM copes with proposals and actions beyond historical experience, allows <strong>for</strong> supply anddemand uncerta<strong>in</strong>ty, and allows <strong>for</strong> passive use values - <strong>the</strong> satisfaction that someth<strong>in</strong>g merelyexists, or is be<strong>in</strong>g preserved <strong>for</strong> o<strong>the</strong>rs <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> future. However, it does have disadvantages.These <strong>in</strong>clude, <strong>for</strong> example: <strong>the</strong> hypo<strong>the</strong>tical will<strong>in</strong>gness to pay overstates real will<strong>in</strong>gness –people tend to assume hypo<strong>the</strong>tical events will happen <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> future; a tendency <strong>for</strong> will<strong>in</strong>gnessto accept exceed<strong>in</strong>g will<strong>in</strong>gness to pay; 72 and a distortive effect if benefits cannot be restrictedto those who pay – <strong>the</strong> ‘free rider’ problem which depresses will<strong>in</strong>gness to pay.Generally recognised national measures such as Gross Domestic Product suffer similar problemswith over-emphasis on monetary measures, 73 so valuation of costs and benefits is not easy, evenat a country level.In practice a more simplistic approach tends to be followed, often consider<strong>in</strong>g only oneoption – ‘should we do this or not?’, ra<strong>the</strong>r than ‘which of several possibilities is best?’ – andsimplify<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> non-quantifiable benefits and costs where <strong>in</strong><strong>for</strong>mation is difficult to come by.For example, it has been observed that <strong>in</strong> studies of <strong>the</strong> effects of air pollution, <strong>the</strong> outcomemeasure has largely been limited to mortality, <strong>for</strong> lack of easily available <strong>in</strong><strong>for</strong>mation onassociated non-fatal illnesses. 74Impact <strong>analysis</strong> also tends to look at ga<strong>in</strong>s and losses on a composite basis ra<strong>the</strong>r than <strong>in</strong> termsof <strong>the</strong> effects on <strong>in</strong>dividuals. Aga<strong>in</strong>, <strong>the</strong> same issues arise that have been considered previously,<strong>for</strong> example:67Centre <strong>for</strong> Economics and Bus<strong>in</strong>ess Research, Regulation <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> Market Place: An Economic Literature Review, <strong>for</strong> <strong>ICAEW</strong>.68EFRAG, Consider<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> Effects of Account<strong>in</strong>g Standards.69Persky, ‘Retrospectives: Cost-Benefit Analysis and <strong>the</strong> Classical Creed’.70Boden, ‘Cost-Benefit Analysis: Caveat Emptor’.71The Economist, ‘The Rule of More’.72Whitehead and Blomquist, ‘The Use of Cont<strong>in</strong>gent Valuation <strong>in</strong> Benefit – Cost Analysis’.73Considered fur<strong>the</strong>r <strong>in</strong> Section 7.2.2.74Boden, ‘Cost-Benefit Analysis: Caveat Emptor’.Credentials <strong>for</strong> <strong>in</strong>vok<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> <strong>public</strong> <strong>in</strong>terest23

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!