12.07.2015 Views

Acting in the public interest – a framework for analysis - ICAEW

Acting in the public interest – a framework for analysis - ICAEW

Acting in the public interest – a framework for analysis - ICAEW

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS
  • No tags were found...

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

In this <strong>in</strong>stance, while national security was considered to carry significant weight<strong>in</strong>g, this wasnot considered an excuse to avoid mitigation of <strong>the</strong> effect.An <strong>in</strong>ternational study on particular medical treatments considered criteria <strong>for</strong> patient selection. 193It found that social value criteria were widely applied. The actual weight<strong>in</strong>gs were largely <strong>the</strong>product of <strong>the</strong> beliefs of <strong>in</strong>dividual doctors, although cl<strong>in</strong>ical criteria were provided by someprofessional bodies. Ano<strong>the</strong>r medical study of 450 dialysis and transplant doctors was able todeterm<strong>in</strong>e a set of weight<strong>in</strong>gs actually applied. They range from medical benefit, with a weight<strong>in</strong>gof 4.2, through, <strong>for</strong> example, will<strong>in</strong>gness – 3.7, age – 2.7, and ability to pay – 1.8, to gender –1.0. 194 Many of <strong>the</strong> aspects considered are clearly removed from broadly based impact criteriaand social value criteria can be seen as arbitrary and unfair. 195 Not least of <strong>the</strong> controversy iswhe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong> decisions should be left to specialists or take <strong>in</strong>to consideration wider <strong>public</strong> views.Sometimes <strong>the</strong>re are absolute values that are so important (<strong>for</strong> example basic human rights)that <strong>the</strong>y need to prevail <strong>in</strong> all but <strong>the</strong> most extreme situations. These can be dealt with by,<strong>in</strong> effect, apply<strong>in</strong>g a weight<strong>in</strong>g of 100% or near to it.8.2.6 Trade-off of <strong>in</strong>terestsGiven conflicts between <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>terests of different elements of <strong>the</strong> relevant <strong>public</strong>, <strong>the</strong> issuearises of whe<strong>the</strong>r it is right and proper to benefit one section of <strong>the</strong> community at <strong>the</strong> expenseof ano<strong>the</strong>r: <strong>in</strong> economic terms, what is maximis<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> end result considered to mean?One measure, known as Pareto efficiency, takes it that output is maximised when it wouldbe impossible to make someone better off, without mak<strong>in</strong>g someone else worse off. Welfareeconomics, which considers distributive economic efficiency, often regards Pareto efficiencyas <strong>the</strong> appropriate measure. In perfectly competitive markets <strong>the</strong>re will be a set of prices atwhich aggregate demand equals aggregate supply <strong>for</strong> each commodity. This is competitiveequilibrium. The key pr<strong>in</strong>ciples of welfare economics are that:• every competitive equilibrium is Pareto efficient; and• every Pareto efficient outcome can be achieved by an appropriate allocation of resources.Extend<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> logic, every Pareto efficient allocation can be changed by reallocationbetween <strong>the</strong> parties <strong>in</strong>volved. 196However, this takes no account of <strong>the</strong> distribution issues that arise if consideration is be<strong>in</strong>ggiven to <strong>in</strong>terfer<strong>in</strong>g with <strong>the</strong> market equilibrium po<strong>in</strong>t <strong>in</strong> order to move to a different po<strong>in</strong>ton an output curve, or a po<strong>in</strong>t on a different curve.Panel 8.4: Pareto allocationConsider an example of possible utility outcomes <strong>for</strong> various parts of a society: 197BCAThe axes show <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g amounts of utility achieved by two different sections of society, <strong>for</strong>different outcomes.Position A represents <strong>the</strong> utility outcome achieved under market equilibrium. However,because of some sort of market failure, government <strong>in</strong>terference to correct that failure couldachieve positions B or C. Both B and C are on higher utility outcome curves than A so bothwould be an advance <strong>in</strong> terms of overall utility, but which, if ei<strong>the</strong>r, is a success?B is on a higher Pareto curve than C so <strong>in</strong> Pareto terms B would be a welfare success and C awelfare failure. However, <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> absence of offsett<strong>in</strong>g transfers (which is a political option), toget from A to B, <strong>the</strong> much higher utility of one section is offset by a small reduction <strong>in</strong> utility<strong>in</strong> ano<strong>the</strong>r section. There is an argument that <strong>in</strong> economic terms, government <strong>in</strong>tervention islegitimate only if <strong>the</strong> position achieved through <strong>in</strong>terference is better, or at least no worse, <strong>in</strong>every way. This would <strong>the</strong> case with outcome C, which marks an improvement <strong>in</strong> utility <strong>for</strong>all sections, but B would be regarded as a failure <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong>se terms.193Quoted <strong>in</strong> Pleasence and Maclean, ‘The Public Interest’.194Quoted <strong>in</strong> Pleasence and Maclean, ibid.195Pleasence and Maclean, ibid.196Kay, The Truth About Markets, Besley, Welfare Economics and Public Choice.197Based on Besley, ibid.58Aggregation and decision

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!