30.01.2013 Views

Download Green Economy Report - UNEP

Download Green Economy Report - UNEP

Download Green Economy Report - UNEP

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

correlated with increased use of non-renewable resource<br />

inputs, and have often entailed significant environmental<br />

costs due to their overuse (Figure 3). Industrial agriculture<br />

consumes on average 10 exosomatic energy calories<br />

(derived from fossil-fuel energy resources) for every<br />

food endosomatic energy calorie (derived from human<br />

metabolism of food) that is produced and delivered to the<br />

consumer (Giampietro and Pimentel 1994). This energyintensity,<br />

in many cases, is encouraged by subsidizing<br />

inorganic fertilizer, fuel and electric power used on<br />

farms. In addition, bio-diversity losses have resulted from<br />

production subsidies targeted at a limited number of<br />

crops. Industrial agriculture has also resulted in shrinking<br />

the agricultural labour force even as farm outputs have<br />

dramatically increased, a trend intensified to some extent<br />

by subsidies for farm mechanization. (Lyson 2005, Dimitri<br />

et al. 2005, Knudsen et al. 2005, ILO 2008).<br />

1.3 Traditional/small farm/<br />

subsistence agriculture<br />

Traditional (subsistence) smallholder agriculture is<br />

typically low-productivity farming practiced on small<br />

plots, with low value added per worker and primarily<br />

reliant on extracting soil nutrients with insufficient<br />

replenishment by either organic or inorganic fertilizers.<br />

It is susceptible to yield losses due to erratic rainfall, pest<br />

and weed infestations and other production-related<br />

risks caused by poor management.<br />

Traditional agriculture has limited scope for farm<br />

mechanization and external agri-chemical inputs.<br />

Many smallholders’ plots, typically located in LICs and<br />

in some LMICs, are too small to realize the economies<br />

of scale required for most commercial farm machinery.<br />

In addition, the high cost of purchased inputs such as<br />

chemical fertilizers generally require that at least some<br />

portion of the crops produced must be sold to recover<br />

costs. Failure to modernize land tenure systems, which<br />

can facilitate distribution, consolidation, and the use of<br />

land as security for bank loans are important barriers to<br />

the commercialization of small-scale agriculture in many<br />

LICs. Commercialization is further limited by inadequate<br />

road transportation linking food-producing areas to<br />

large urban centers. For these reasons, value added per<br />

worker in LICs is far below that of HICs. Whereas the<br />

average value added per agricultural worker in OECD<br />

countries in 2003 was US$23,081 (which grew at 4.4<br />

per cent per year between 1992 and 2003, in Africa, the<br />

figures were only US$327 and 1.4 per cent, respectively<br />

(IAASTD 2009b).<br />

Worldwide, there are 525 million small farms, 404 million<br />

of which operate on less than two hectares of land<br />

(Nagayets 2005). These farmers account for a sizable share<br />

of global agricultural production (70 per cent) and in many<br />

Box 1: Agriculture at a<br />

crossroads<br />

The key message of the Assessment of Agricultural<br />

Knowledge, Science and Technology for<br />

Development, published in 2009 is: “The way the<br />

world grows its food will have to change radically<br />

to better serve the poor and hungry if the world<br />

is to cope with a growing population and climate<br />

change while avoiding social breakdown and<br />

environmental collapse.” The Assessment calls for<br />

a fundamental shift in agricultural knowledge,<br />

science and technology (AKST) to successfully<br />

meet development and sustainability objectives.<br />

Such a shift should emphasize the importance<br />

of the multi-functionality of agriculture,<br />

accounting for the complexity of agricultural<br />

systems within diverse social and ecological<br />

contexts and recognizing farming communities,<br />

farm households, and farmers as producers and<br />

managers of ecosystems. Innovative institutional<br />

and organizational arrangements to promote<br />

an integrated approach to the development<br />

and deployment of AKST are required as<br />

well. Incentives along the value chain should<br />

internalize as many negative externalities as<br />

possible, to account for the full cost of agricultural<br />

production to society. Policy and institutional<br />

changes should focus on those least served in the<br />

current AKST approaches, including resourcepoor<br />

farmers, women and ethnic minorities. It<br />

emphasizes that small-scale farms across diverse<br />

ecosystems need realistic opportunities to<br />

increase productivity and access markets.<br />

Figure 4: Regional distribution of small farms<br />

Source: Nagayets (2005)<br />

Agriculture<br />

41

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!