19.08.2013 Views

AP Econ Module 30 Deficits Debt - Sunny Hills High School

AP Econ Module 30 Deficits Debt - Sunny Hills High School

AP Econ Module 30 Deficits Debt - Sunny Hills High School

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

2.7yo of GDP-9383 billion-in interest on its debt. And although this is a relatively<br />

large fraction ofGDP, other countries p ay even greater frartions oftheir GDp to service<br />

their debt. For example, in 2009, Greece paid interest ofabout S.4% ofcDp.<br />

Other things equal, a govemment paying Large sums in interest must raise more revenue<br />

from taxes or spend less than it would otherwise be able to afford-or it must borrow<br />

even more to cover the gap. And a government that borrows to pay interesr on irs<br />

outstanding debt pushes itselfeven deeper into debt. This process can evenrually push<br />

a govemment to the point at which lenders question its abfiry to repay. Like consumers<br />

who have maxed out their credit cards, the govemnent will find that lenders<br />

are unwilling to lend any more funds. The result can be thar rhe government defaults<br />

on its debt-it srops pafng what it owes. Default is often followed by deep financial<br />

and economic turmoil.<br />

The idea of a government defaulring sounds far-fetched,<br />

but it is not impossible. In the 1990s, Argentina, a relatively<br />

high-income developing country was widely praised for its<br />

econornic policies-and it was able to borrow large sums from<br />

foreign lenders. By 2001, however, Argentina's interest payments<br />

were spiraling out ofcontrol and the country stopped<br />

paying the sums that were due. Default creates havoc in a<br />

country's financial markets and badly shakes public confidence<br />

in both the government and the economy, Argentina's<br />

debt default was accompaaied by a crisis in the country's<br />

banking system and a very severe recession. And even if a<br />

highly indebted govemment avoids default, a heavy debt burden<br />

typically forces it to slash spending or raise taxes, politically<br />

unpopular measures that can also damage the econorny.<br />

One question some people ask is: can't a govemment that has t(ouble borrowing just<br />

print money to pay irs bills? Yes, it can, but this leads to another problem: inflation. In<br />

fart, budget problems are the main cause ofvery severe inflacion, as we'Il see later. The<br />

point for now is that governments do not want to find themselves in a position where<br />

the choice is between defaulting on their debts and inflating those debts away.<br />

Concerns about the long-run effects of deficits need not rule out the use of fiscal<br />

polici' to stimulate the economy when it is depressed. However, these concems do<br />

mean that governments should try to offset budget deficits in bad years with budget<br />

surpluses in good years. In other words, governments should run a budget that is approxirnately<br />

balanced over time. Have they actually done so?<br />

<strong>Deficits</strong> and <strong>Debt</strong> in Practice<br />

Figure <strong>30</strong>.4 on the next page shows how the U.S. federal govemmenc's budget deficit<br />

and its debt have evolved since 1940. Panel (a) shows the federal deficir as a percentage<br />

of GDP. As you can see, the federal govemment ran huge deficits during World W'ar II.<br />

It briefly ran surpluses after the war, but it has normally run deficits ever since, especially<br />

after 1980. This seems inconsistent with the advice that governments should offset<br />

deficits in bad times with surpluses in good times.<br />

However, panel (b) ofFigure <strong>30</strong>.4 shows that these deficits have not led to runaway<br />

debt. To assess the ability of governments to pay their debr, we often use the debt-<br />

GDP ratio, the governmenCs debt as a percentage ofGDP. W'e use this measure, raaher<br />

than simply looking at the size ofthe debt because GDP, which measures the size ofthe<br />

economy as a whole, is a good indicator oFthe potential taxes the government cal collect.<br />

Ifthe governmenCs debt grows more slowly than GDP, the burden ofpafng that<br />

debt is actua-lly fa-lling compared with the governmenCs porential rax revenue.<br />

What we see from panel (b) is that although the federal debt has grown in almost<br />

eyery year, the debt-cDP ratio fell for <strong>30</strong> years after the end of World War II. This<br />

shows that the debt-GDP ratio can fall, even when debr is rising, as long as GDP grows<br />

faster than debt. Growth and inflation sometimes allow a govemment that runs persistent<br />

budget deficits to nevertheless have a declining debt-GDP rado.<br />

m o d u le 3 0 Long-run lmplications of Fiscal Policy: <strong>Deficits</strong><br />

Lautario Palacios, T, holds a<br />

sign that calls forpotiticlans to<br />

stop robblng, durlng a January 9,<br />

2oo2 demonstlatlon ln Buenos<br />

Aires, Argentina.<br />

fte debt-G0P ratio is he government's<br />

debt as a percentage of GDP,<br />

and the Public Dsbl <strong>30</strong>1

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!