26.10.2014 Views

Review of Austrian Economics - The Ludwig von Mises Institute

Review of Austrian Economics - The Ludwig von Mises Institute

Review of Austrian Economics - The Ludwig von Mises Institute

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

Higgs: Analysis <strong>of</strong> the Growth <strong>of</strong> Government 23<br />

as the indexes used to measure it mean what they are supposed to<br />

mean.<br />

Elsewhere, I have tried to clarify the concept <strong>of</strong> ideology, to show<br />

how ideology can be understood as consistent with rather than the<br />

antithesis <strong>of</strong> rational action, and to document how ideology affected<br />

and in turn was affected by the growth <strong>of</strong> American government over<br />

the past century (Higgs 1983; 1985; 1987a; 1989c). I shall not repeat<br />

everything I have written on this subject, but one point requires<br />

restatement and emphasis.<br />

<strong>The</strong> existing thrust <strong>of</strong> the economic literature, the quest to determine<br />

econometrically whether ideology mattered in determining a<br />

certain set <strong>of</strong> political actions, seeks to answer a non-question. Of<br />

course it matters. It always matters, because people cannot even<br />

think about political questions, much less undertake political actions,<br />

without an ideology (Siegenthaler 1989; Higgs 1989a; 1989c, pp.<br />

98-100).<br />

How can I make such a claim? Economists are supposed to<br />

believe, or at least to postulate for analytical purposes, that people<br />

pursue their "economic interests." Open any mainstream text on<br />

economic theory and check the arguments <strong>of</strong> the utility function: sure<br />

enough, they consist <strong>of</strong> amounts <strong>of</strong> "goods" consumed by the individual;<br />

nothing about ideas here, just pounds <strong>of</strong> potatoes, bottles <strong>of</strong> beer,<br />

trips to the shore, hours <strong>of</strong> leisure, and so forth. In the words <strong>of</strong><br />

Gary Becker (1983, p. 374, emphasis added), "the utility <strong>of</strong> each<br />

person . . . depends only on own commodities." To consume more <strong>of</strong><br />

these things is, the mainstream economist supposes, precisely what<br />

is meant when one speaks <strong>of</strong> people's acting in their self-interest. In<br />

this context, to speak <strong>of</strong> a person's economic or material interest<br />

would be redundant, because the theory recognizes no other kind.<br />

Thus, Thomas Borcherding (1985, p. 378, emphasis added) declares<br />

it "an open question whether after the obvious elements <strong>of</strong> self-interest<br />

are separated from political action, scope for ideology remains."<br />

<strong>The</strong> most charitable thing I can say about this view is that it is<br />

simply wrong. No one ever explained why it is wrong more clearly<br />

and succinctly than <strong>Mises</strong> (1957, pp. 140, 142, emphasis added):<br />

In the world <strong>of</strong> reality, life, and human action there is no such thing<br />

as interests independent <strong>of</strong> ideas, preceding them temporally and<br />

logically. What a man considers his interest is the result <strong>of</strong> his ideas.<br />

. . . Free men do not act in accordance with their interests. <strong>The</strong>y act<br />

in accordance with what they believe furthers their interests.<br />

Nor are the <strong>Austrian</strong>s alone in appreciating the dependence <strong>of</strong> interest<br />

on belief. Jon Elster (1989, p. 20), for example, recently wrote:

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!