26.01.2015 Views

Volume II - PDF - International Association of Deposit Insurers

Volume II - PDF - International Association of Deposit Insurers

Volume II - PDF - International Association of Deposit Insurers

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS
  • No tags were found...

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

•BACKGROUND DOCUMENTS•<br />

Part <strong>II</strong>: Outreach<br />

That action, he said, involved a cost that, under<br />

modern legislation, would be paid for by the<br />

members and users <strong>of</strong> the financial system. The<br />

supervisor could reduce that cost by taking prompt<br />

action to detect and remedy problems in the<br />

banking system.<br />

Permissive action by the lender <strong>of</strong> last resort could<br />

harm the deposit insurance fund, said Dr. Jaime. A<br />

troubled bank requesting lender-<strong>of</strong>-last-resort<br />

assistance would give its best assets as collateral for<br />

this assistance, which would go to benefit the weak<br />

bank’s most restless depositors—those who were<br />

not guaranteed and thus sought to withdraw their<br />

funds. Such action would increase the final cost to<br />

the insurer. Dr. Jaime set out how each <strong>of</strong> the three<br />

components <strong>of</strong> the financial safety net should<br />

behave. The lender <strong>of</strong> last resort should (1) limit<br />

spillover by lending funds that would be quickly<br />

recovered because they were paid only to illiquid<br />

but solvent banks, (2) provide assistance without<br />

expanding the monetary base, and (3) have an<br />

asset base that enabled it to sterilize assistance. He<br />

stated that, despite popular belief, even central<br />

banks in countries with a currency board were able<br />

to act as lenders <strong>of</strong> last resort if they had the<br />

appropriate assets on their balance sheets.<br />

The speaker observed that the supervisor required<br />

a legal/prudential framework that strengthened<br />

banks’ solvency and liquidity without hindering<br />

the work <strong>of</strong> markets. Thus, the Basel Committee’s<br />

Core Principles must be followed. In practice, the<br />

supervisor must be preventive and do more than<br />

just monitor ex post compliance with prudential<br />

regulations. The deposit insurer protected insured<br />

depositors when a bank failed so there should be<br />

no excuse for delayed supervisory action. No banker<br />

should benefit from, or be protected during, the<br />

winding up <strong>of</strong> his bank. Resolutions that in fact<br />

covered all liabilities at a “too-big-to-fail” bank<br />

violated this principle and led to ambiguity that<br />

was in no way constructive. Such resolutions also<br />

raised costs to the surviving banks.<br />

A sound government budget, absence <strong>of</strong> inflation,<br />

strong supervision, and politicians who did not<br />

meddle were all prerequisites for the establishment<br />

<strong>of</strong> a system <strong>of</strong> deposit insurance and for the better<br />

functioning <strong>of</strong> the financial system. Further, the<br />

safety net needed to function as a virtuous triangle<br />

with its three components acting in harmony.<br />

In its turn, the deposit insurer should resolve<br />

problem banks with a minimum commitment <strong>of</strong><br />

funds and a maximum recovery <strong>of</strong> those expended.<br />

Moreover, the deposit insurer should not act as<br />

payer <strong>of</strong> last resort to the lender <strong>of</strong> last resort.<br />

Mr. Carl Tannenbaum <strong>of</strong> ABN AMRO (a large,<br />

Dutch, international bank holding company)<br />

spoke first for the discussants. In introducing him,<br />

Mr. Evan<strong>of</strong>f pointed out that Mr. Tannenbaum<br />

was the only practicing banker on the program—his<br />

bank paid deposit insurance premiums and footed<br />

the bill for others’ mistakes. Mr. Tannenbaum said<br />

that, while he was aware that there were alternatives<br />

to deposit insurance, he nevertheless was<br />

supportive <strong>of</strong> its aims to stabilize markets and<br />

assure the interests <strong>of</strong> small depositors. From a<br />

banker’s perspective, it reduced volatility, lowered<br />

the cost <strong>of</strong> capital, and built a stronger currency.<br />

He regretted, however, that private suppliers <strong>of</strong><br />

deposit protection had insufficient funds and<br />

credibility to take over the government’s role.<br />

Mr. Tannenbaum doubted the ability <strong>of</strong> deposit<br />

insurance to achieve the objectives attributed to it<br />

in the paper on public policy objectives. Achieving<br />

financial stability, for example, would require 100<br />

percent coverage, because the flight <strong>of</strong> large pools<br />

<strong>of</strong> uninsured money would be destabilizing. There<br />

was a danger that protection would extend beyond<br />

banks—for example, even commercial firms might<br />

be backstopped by the deposit insurance system<br />

under Holland’s universal banking system. One<br />

impediment to deposit insurance’s success was<br />

poor processing <strong>of</strong> information. Here he stressed<br />

the role that private rating agencies for banks<br />

played in providing information to the markets<br />

and the sophisticated public in the United States.<br />

Mr. Tannenbaum observed that reliance on<br />

supervision, regulation, capital requirements, and<br />

disclosure to thwart moral hazard, as recommended<br />

165<br />

Guidance for Developing Effective <strong>Deposit</strong> Insurance Systems: <strong>Volume</strong> <strong>II</strong>

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!