25.06.2015 Views

8 Oligopoly - Luiscabral.net

8 Oligopoly - Luiscabral.net

8 Oligopoly - Luiscabral.net

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

solution, not surprisingly, is for Firm 1 to chose the monopoly quantity: q1 ∗(0) = qM , where<br />

q M is the monopoly quantity. If Firm 2 were to chose the quantity corresponding to perfect<br />

competition, that is q 2 = q C , where q C is such that P (q C ) = c, then Firm 1’s optimum<br />

would be to produce zero: q1 ∗(qC ) = 0. In fact, this is the point at which marginal cost<br />

intercepts the marginal revenue corresponding to d 1 (q C ).<br />

It can be shown that, given a linear demand and constant marginal cost, the function<br />

q1 ∗(q 2) — Firm 1’s best response mapping — is also linear. Since we have two points, we<br />

can draw the entire function q1 ∗(q 2). This is done in Figure 8.6. Notice that the axes are<br />

now different from the previous figures. On the horizontal axis, we continue measuring<br />

quantities, specifically, Firm 2’s quantity, q 2 . On the vertical axis, we now measure Firm<br />

1’s quantity, q 1 , not price.<br />

Algebraic derivation. Throughout this chapter, in parallel with the graphical derivation<br />

of equilibria, I also present the correponding algebraic derivation. Except for some results<br />

in the next section, algebra is not necessary for the derivation of the main results; but it<br />

may help, especially if you are familiar with basic algebra and calculus. Let me start with<br />

the algebraic derivation of Firm 1’s best response. Suppose that (inverse) demand is given<br />

by P (Q) = a − b Q, whereas cost is given by C(q) = c q, where q is the firm’s output and<br />

Q = q 1 + q 2 is total output.<br />

Firm 1’s profit is<br />

π 1 = P q 1 − C(q 1 ) = ( a − b (q 1 + q 2 ) ) q 1 − c q 1<br />

The first-order condition for the maximization of π 1 with respect to q 1 , ∂ π 1 /∂ q 1 = 0, is<br />

or simply<br />

−b q 1 + a − b (q 1 + q 2 ) − c = 0<br />

q 1 = a − c − q 2<br />

2 b 2<br />

Since this gives the optimum q 1 for each value of q 2 , we have just derived the Firm 1’s<br />

best response, q1(q ∗ 2 ):<br />

q ∗ 1(q 2 ) = a − c<br />

2 b<br />

− q 2<br />

2<br />

(1)<br />

We are now ready for the last step in our analysis, that of finding the equilibrium. An<br />

equilibrium is a point at which firms choose optimal quantities given what they conjecture<br />

the other firm does; and those conjectures are correct. Specifically, an equilibrium will<br />

correspond to a pair of values (q 1 , q 2 ) such that q 1 is Firm 1’s optimal response given q 2<br />

and, conversely, q 2 is Firm 2’s optimal response given q 1 .<br />

We have not derived Firm 2’s best response. However, given our assumption that both<br />

firms have the same cost function, we conclude that Firm 2’s best response, q2 ∗(q 1), is the<br />

symmetric of Firm 1’s. We can thus proceed to plot the two best responses in the same<br />

graph, as in Figure 8.6.<br />

As in the case of the Bertrand model (see Section 8.8.1), the equilibrium point in the<br />

Cournot model is then given by the intersection of the best response mappings, point N. In

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!