25.06.2015 Views

8 Oligopoly - Luiscabral.net

8 Oligopoly - Luiscabral.net

8 Oligopoly - Luiscabral.net

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

Figure 8.1<br />

Bertrand game with limited number of price choices<br />

Firm 1<br />

5<br />

4<br />

3<br />

Firm 2<br />

5 4 3<br />

7.5 12 7<br />

7.5 0 0<br />

0 6 7<br />

12 6 0<br />

0 0 3.5<br />

7 7 3.5<br />

both firms are better off by setting a high price; (b) however, given that both firms set a<br />

high price, both firms have an incentive to undercut the rival.<br />

The above game is based on a number of simplifying assumptions. In particular, I am<br />

restricting firms to set prices at integer values (3, 4 or 5). What if Firm 1 could undercut<br />

p 2 = 5 by setting p 1 = 4.99? In the next paragraphs, I consider the more general case when<br />

firms can set any value of p i , in fact any real value. As we will see, the main qualitative<br />

results and intuition remain valid. In fact, in some sense the result will be even more<br />

extreme.<br />

The continuous case. Suppose now that firms can set any value of p from 0 to +∞,<br />

including non-integer values. Now we are unable to describe the game as a matrix of<br />

strategies (there are infinitely many strategies). However, we can derive, as before, each<br />

firm’s best response mapping, from which we can then derive the Nash equilibrium. Recall<br />

that firm i’s best response p ∗ i (p j) is a mapping that gives, for each price by firm j, firm i’s<br />

optimal price. The only novelty with respect to the discrete case is that the values of p j<br />

and p i now vary continuously.<br />

Suppose that Firm 1 expects Firm 2 to price above monopoly price. Then Firm 1’s<br />

optimal strategy is to price at the monopoly level. In fact, by doing so Firm 1 gets all of the<br />

demand and receives monopoly profits (the maximum possible profits). If Firm 1 expects<br />

Firm 2 to price below monopoly price but above marginal cost, then Firm 1’s optimal<br />

strategy is to set a price just below Firm 2’s: c pricing above would lead to zero demand<br />

and zero profits; and pricing below gives firm i all of the market demand, but lower profits<br />

the lower the price is. Finally, if Firm 1 expects Firm 2 to price below marginal cost, then<br />

Firm 1 optimal choice is to price higher than Firm 2, say, at marginal cost level.<br />

Figure 8.2 depicts Firm 1’s best response, p ∗ 1 (p 2), in a graph with each firm’s strategy<br />

on each axis. Consistent with the above derivation, for values of p 2 less than MC , Firm 1<br />

chooses p 1 = MC = c. For values of p 2 greater than MC but lower than p M , Firm 1 chooses<br />

p 1 just below p 2 . Finally, for values of p 2 greater than monopoly price, p M , Firm 1 chooses<br />

c. What does “just below” mean? If p 1 could be any real number, than “just below” would not be well<br />

defined: there exists no real number “just below” another real number. In practice, prices have to<br />

be set on a finite grid (in cents of the dollar, for example), in which case “just below” would mean<br />

one cent less. This points to an important assumption of the Bertrand model: Firm 1 will steal all<br />

of Firm 2’s demand even if its price is only one cent lower than the rival’s.

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!