25.06.2015 Views

8 Oligopoly - Luiscabral.net

8 Oligopoly - Luiscabral.net

8 Oligopoly - Luiscabral.net

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

Monopoly, duopoly, and perfect competition. Duopoly is an intermediate market<br />

structure, between monopoly (maximum concentration of market shares) and perfect competition<br />

(minimum concentration of market shares). One would expect equilibrium price<br />

and output under duopoly also to lie between the extremes of monopoly and perfect competition.<br />

This fact can be checked based on Figure 8.6. Recall that each firm’s best response<br />

intercepts the axes at the values q M and q C . Therefore, a line with slope −1 intersecting<br />

the axes at the farther extremes of the best response mappings unites all points such that<br />

̂q 1 +̂q 2 = q C (line C in Figure 8.6). Likewise, a line with slope −1 intersecting the axes at the<br />

closer extremes of the best response mappings unites all points such that ̂q 1 + ̂q 2 = q M (line<br />

M in Figure 8.6). We can see that the Cournot equilibrium point, N, lies between these<br />

two lines. This implies that total output under Cournot is greater than under monopoly<br />

and lower than under perfect competition.<br />

To summarize,<br />

Under output competition (Cournot), equilibrium output is greater than monopoly<br />

output and lower than perfect competition output. Likewise, duopoly price is lower<br />

than monopoly price and greater than price under perfect competition.<br />

See Exercise 8.14 for the analytical version of this idea. In Chapter 10, I present a more<br />

general result: in an oligopoly with n firms, equilibrium price is closer to perfect competition<br />

the greater n is.<br />

A “dynamic” interpretation of the Cournot equilibrium. It is easy to understand why<br />

the Cournot equilibrium is a stable solution: no firm would have an incentive to choose<br />

a different output. In other words, each firm is choosing an optimal strategy given the<br />

strategy chosen by its rival. But: is the Cournot equilibrium a realistic prediction of what<br />

will happen in reality?<br />

The equilibrium concept we have used is that of Nash equilibrium, first introduced in<br />

Chapter 7. There I presented a variety of possible justifications for the concept of Nash<br />

equilibrium. Here I present an argument, first proposed by Cournot himself, which is similar<br />

to the idea of solution by elimination of dominated strategies.<br />

Although the Cournot model is a static game, let us consider the following dynamic<br />

interpretation. At time t = 1, Firm 1 chooses some output level. Then, at time t = 2, Firm<br />

2 chooses the optimal output level given Firm 1’s output choice. At time t = 3, it’s again<br />

Firm 1’s turn to choose an optimal output given Firm 2’s current output; and so on: Firm<br />

1 chooses output at odd time periods, and Firm 2 at even time periods.<br />

Figure 8.7 gives an idea of what this dynamic process might look like. We start from<br />

a point in the horizontal axis (q2 ◦ , Firm 2’s output at time zero). At time t = 1, we move<br />

vertically towards Firm 1’s best response (Firm 1 is optimizing). At time t = 2, we move<br />

horizontally to Firm 2’s best response (Firm 2 is optimizing). At time t = 3, we move<br />

again vertically toward Firm 1’s best response. And so on. As can be seen from the figure,<br />

the dynamic process converges to the Cournot equilibrium. In fact, no matter what the<br />

initial situation, we always converge to the Nash equilibrium. This is reassuring, insofar as<br />

it provides an additional motivation for the idea of Cournot equilibrium.

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!