08.09.2016 Views

WEALTH

2c0esX1

2c0esX1

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

MACRO<br />

to 2007 encouraged a belief in stability that lulled<br />

complacent policymakers and regulators into ignoring the<br />

dangers of dubious practices that set up a fragile and<br />

unstable financial system.<br />

“The other thing worth observing,” Eichengreen says,<br />

“is that it is also remarkable that we weren’t more aware of<br />

those parallels and their implications – that it could all end<br />

horribly – while they were unfolding.”<br />

What went wrong? “I think the big mistakes, the major<br />

examples of wrong lessons, were the decisions made before<br />

the recent crisis.” These included the failure to strengthen<br />

financial regulation and deal with the derivatives problem;<br />

the dismantling of Glass-Steagall in the United States; and<br />

the enthusiasm for light-touch regulation.<br />

HISTORY SURE CAN RHYME<br />

Yet if mistakes were made before 2008, decisions made that<br />

year show that if history does not repeat, it sure can rhyme.<br />

While the Fed rescued the investment bank Bear Stearns,<br />

much as the interwar Fed had done for the Central Republic<br />

of Chicago, it balked at bailing out Lehman Brothers, just as<br />

in 1933 it chose to make a statement by letting Henry Ford’s<br />

Union Guardian Trust of Michigan go under.<br />

“One might think that this history would have informed<br />

decision-making,” Eichengreen writes. “In the heat of the<br />

moment, it did not.” In the case of Guardian Trust, that<br />

created long lines of depositors clamoring outside banks<br />

across the United States, and sent the financial system into<br />

free fall.<br />

“Recent decision-makers were blindsided by history,”<br />

he told PROJECT M. “History informed their decisions<br />

of how to respond but it also blinded them to risks that<br />

had no parallel.”<br />

Eichengreen argues that the single most influential<br />

analysis of the Depression was A Monetary History of the<br />

United States, 1867–1960, written in 1963 by Nobel Prizewinning<br />

economist Milton Friedman and Anna J. Schwartz.<br />

Their 110-page chapter on the 1930s focused on the collapse<br />

of the banking system that made the Depression “Great.”<br />

For Eichengreen, policymakers interpreted Friedman<br />

too literally. The problem of retail bank runs had been<br />

solved, thanks to the 1930s innovation of deposit insurance,<br />

so the panicked bank runs of the Great Depression could be<br />

avoided. But by focusing on monetary supply and banking,<br />

modern policymakers missed the dangers lurking in the<br />

shadow banking system (hedge funds, money market<br />

mutual funds and commercial paper issuers) until too late.<br />

“There was no significant shadow banking in the<br />

1930s, so Friedman and Schwartz didn’t emphasize it,” he<br />

explains. When Lehman failed, money market funds<br />

holding short-term notes suffered runs by frightened<br />

shareholders. Large investors then made runs on the<br />

money funds’ investment bank parents, leading to the<br />

collapse of the securitization market. This caught<br />

policymakers and central bankers totally off guard.<br />

When the markets imploded, unlike in the 1930s,<br />

governments realized they were on the brink of depression,<br />

so they quickly intervened. They ramped up massive<br />

programs of fiscal spending, and central banks flooded<br />

markets with liquidity until a semblance of economic<br />

normality returned. A catastrophic worldwide depression<br />

was avoided, but is collegial backslapping justified?<br />

Eichengreen doesn’t believe so, arguing that the<br />

interventions were far less effective than they could have<br />

been. Post-crisis recovery in the US has been disappointing<br />

by any measure, while Europe experienced double-dip<br />

recession and a series of renewed crises starting in 2010.<br />

But because the recent crisis was less severe than the<br />

Depression, at least in the US, bankers have also been able<br />

to resist making radical reforms, leaving the world<br />

vulnerable to new financial shocks. “Success,” he concludes,<br />

“was also the mother of failure.”<br />

What is needed, as Eichengreen summarized to<br />

PROJECT M, is to require banks, especially big ones, to hold<br />

significantly more capital. He also argues that the conflict<br />

of interest of credit rating agencies – acting as advisor on<br />

how to obtain Triple A ratings and also conferring them –<br />

has to be resolved.<br />

Shadow banking remains a threat. Risks have been<br />

moved into clearinghouses, but concentrated rather than<br />

eliminated. “Moving derivatives onto electronic exchanges<br />

where they can clear as soon as they are done is what<br />

is needed,” he states. “And if some derivatives are too<br />

complicated, too complex, too exotic, too thinly created to<br />

be moved onto exchanges, then it is a good argument for<br />

regulating them out of existence.”<br />

So, what of the future? Eichengreen eschews the notion<br />

of “lesson” when it comes to history, but if the past holds a<br />

parallel relevant for the Fed today, it comes not from the<br />

1930s, but from 1929. That year, concerned about excess on<br />

Wall Street, the Fed raised interest rates to deflate the<br />

bubble. It succeeded beyond expectations, setting up<br />

conditions for the Great Depression.<br />

“If you are concerned about deleveraging, imbalances<br />

and excessive risk taking in the financial sector, there<br />

are instruments better suited for addressing those<br />

risks,” he says. “That is regulation, what is called macroprudential<br />

policies, where regulators clamp down on<br />

margin purchases of securities on risky lending.<br />

Raising interest rates increases the danger that the<br />

economy will tank. It is what the Fed did in 1929 and what<br />

the Fed should avoid today.”<br />

56 • Allianz

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!