23.01.2014 Views

Estimation in Financial Models - RiskLab

Estimation in Financial Models - RiskLab

Estimation in Financial Models - RiskLab

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

wonder why people still use the Black-Scholes formula, s<strong>in</strong>ce it is based on<br />

such simple assumptions { unrealistically simple assumptions". Black [11]).<br />

In real life volatility is not constant at all. It is non-uniform, that means on<br />

days with major economic events volatility is usually higher than on other<br />

days (especially on non-trad<strong>in</strong>g days). In addition, sometimes stock prices<br />

jump which can be thought of as a sudden large <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> the stock's<br />

volatility. Furthermore many economic time series have a mean-reversion<br />

tendency: when the value of a random variable reaches a very high level then<br />

it will rather go down than up and vice versa. Put dierently, it tends away<br />

from extremely high or low values and reverts to some long-term mean.<br />

All these observations lead to the assumption that volatility is a random variable<br />

and a lot of stochastic volatility models have been recently <strong>in</strong>troduced<br />

<strong>in</strong> the literature.<br />

Now the question arises <strong>in</strong> which way stochastic volatility 2 t = 2 (t; !) can<br />

be modeled. The standard framework assumes the volatility specication<br />

dv = m(v) dt + k(v) d ~W t ; (1.3)<br />

with v = 2 t or v = ln 2 t and ~ W t a Wiener process. Out of the variety of<br />

stochastic volatility models we will consider the follow<strong>in</strong>g two:<br />

I: dH t = ( t , 2 t<br />

2 ) dt + t dW t<br />

dv t = ( , v t ) dt + d~W t ; with v t =ln 2 t (1.4)<br />

II: dH t = ( t , 2 t<br />

2 ) dt + t dW t<br />

dv t = b (a , v t ) dt + c p v t d ~W t ; with v t = 2 t (1.5)<br />

where ; ; ; a; b and c are xed constants, W t and W ~ t are <strong>in</strong>dependent<br />

Wiener processes.<br />

In the model (1.4) volatility, ormore exactly ln 2 , is governed by an arithmetic<br />

Ornste<strong>in</strong>-Uhlenbeck (or rst order autoregressive) process with a meanrevert<strong>in</strong>g<br />

tendency. A large and grow<strong>in</strong>g literature treats this case as an<br />

empirically relevant one (see Bollerslev, Engle and Nelson [14], Ste<strong>in</strong> and<br />

Ste<strong>in</strong> [72], Wigg<strong>in</strong>s [75]). In (1.5) a square root diusion model for stochastic<br />

volatility is suggested. For this model see Ball [1] and literature given there.<br />

One further reason why we have restricted our attention to the models (1.4)<br />

and (1.5) above is to be able to show explicitly how certa<strong>in</strong> statistical estimation<br />

procedures are to be implemented and also compared and contrasted<br />

<strong>in</strong> a specic nance context. Most of the techniques <strong>in</strong>troduced do apply to<br />

much more general set-ups.<br />

6

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!