18.04.2015 Views

Mileage-Based User Fee Winners and Losers - RAND Corporation

Mileage-Based User Fee Winners and Losers - RAND Corporation

Mileage-Based User Fee Winners and Losers - RAND Corporation

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

MPG Difference between Household’s Most <strong>and</strong> Least Efficient Vehicles<br />

In this model, households are not allowed to change the number or type of vehicles owned<br />

<strong>and</strong> how much these are driven in response to changes in tax policy. Further, in households owning<br />

more than one vehicle, the share of annual VMT per vehicle is held constant. These are very strong<br />

assumptions made to simplify the model that may or may not be reasonable. In fact, they may be<br />

reasonable assumptions given the relatively small change in the price per mile for most households<br />

for most of the alternatives. Households with more than one vehicle do have more short-run<br />

flexibility that other households do not have <strong>and</strong> may be less sensitive to changes in price. It was<br />

previously demonstrated that households with more than one vehicle have lower price elasticity. This<br />

variable shows that households with vehicles of various fuel efficiencies have a “substitute” that<br />

allows them to be less sensitive to changes in price because they can switch some driving to other<br />

vehicles should the price increase or, for that matter, decrease. Instead of explicitly modeling how<br />

much each household chooses to drive each vehicle, this model uses an interaction term to allow the<br />

price elasticity to vary.<br />

In previous research, a dummy variable has been used to indicate whether a household owns<br />

a “substitute” vehicle. This variable is set equal to one if a household owns more than one type of<br />

vehicle, for example an SUV <strong>and</strong> a pickup. This dummy variable is interacted with price <strong>and</strong> has the<br />

effect of reducing the price elasticity of dem<strong>and</strong> (McMullen, Zhang, <strong>and</strong> Nakahara 2010). While<br />

multiple types of vehicles are positively correlated with VMT, the interaction term is not statistically<br />

significant in McMullen, Zhang, <strong>and</strong> Nakahara (2010). This may be because the type of vehicle is<br />

not a very good predictor of MPG; there are fuel efficient small pickups <strong>and</strong> fuel inefficient sports<br />

cars, for example. The range of fuel efficiency is particularly large among automobiles. Therefore a<br />

household can have a legitimate MPG substitute with two cars while another that owns a van <strong>and</strong> a<br />

SUV may not have a legitimate MPG substitute.<br />

Weatherford (2011) proposes an improvement to this approach by introducing a second<br />

dummy variable indicating whether or not a household owns two or more vehicles where the MPG<br />

of one of the vehicles is 20 percent or more fuel efficient than the average MPG of the household.<br />

This variable more clearly indicates whether or not the household has a vehicle that is more, or less,<br />

fuel efficient than the others owned by the household, regardless of type. It is problematic, however,<br />

in that the 20 percent threshold is arbitrary.<br />

This study introduces a continuous alternative to the MPG “substitute” variable in using the<br />

percentage difference between the most fuel efficient <strong>and</strong> the least fuel efficient vehicle in the<br />

household. This household MPG range variable addresses both of the concerns raised above <strong>and</strong><br />

indicates not only whether a household owns a vehicle that is a “substitute” based entirely on MPG<br />

criteria, but also captures how good a substitute that vehicle is. Because the price elasticity works in<br />

both directions, it is important to use a variable for which the coefficient will always have the same<br />

sign.<br />

The percentage difference is calculated by dividing the MPG of the household’s least<br />

efficient vehicle from the MPG of the household’s most efficient vehicle <strong>and</strong> then dividing that<br />

difference by the MPG of the most efficient vehicle. For this variable, 36 percent of households<br />

have a value of zero because they either have only one vehicle or, in relatively rare cases, have two<br />

vehicles with the same MPG. 33 The distribution of this variable, in Figure 3.4 shows that many<br />

households with two or more vehicles have a non-trivial difference in the fuel economy between<br />

their most <strong>and</strong> least fuel efficient vehicles. The percentage difference in MPG between the most <strong>and</strong><br />

33 Only 345 observations with a value of zero for this variable, less than 1 percent, own two or more vehicles.<br />

Page 38 of 131

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!