12.07.2015 Views

"Top Incomes in the Long Run of History" with Tony Atkinson and

"Top Incomes in the Long Run of History" with Tony Atkinson and

"Top Incomes in the Long Run of History" with Tony Atkinson and

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

Atk<strong>in</strong>son, Piketty, <strong>and</strong> Saez: <strong>Top</strong> <strong>Incomes</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>Long</strong> <strong>Run</strong> <strong>of</strong> History35to an underestimation <strong>of</strong> top <strong>in</strong>come shares.Ideally, one would want to impute excludedcapital <strong>in</strong>come back to each <strong>in</strong>come group.Because <strong>of</strong> lack <strong>of</strong> data, such an imputationis very difficult to fully carry out. 25 Some <strong>of</strong><strong>the</strong> studies discuss whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong> exclusion <strong>of</strong>capital <strong>in</strong>come affects <strong>the</strong> series. For example,Chiaki Moriguchi <strong>and</strong> Saez (2008), <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong>case <strong>of</strong> Japan, use survey data to estimate how<strong>in</strong>terest <strong>in</strong>come—today almost completelyexcluded from <strong>the</strong> comprehensive <strong>in</strong>come taxbase <strong>in</strong> Japan—is distributed across <strong>in</strong>comegroups. In <strong>the</strong> case <strong>of</strong> France, Piketty (2001,2003) has shown that <strong>the</strong> long-run decl<strong>in</strong>e <strong>of</strong>top <strong>in</strong>come shares was robust <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> sense thateven an upper bound imputation <strong>of</strong> today’stax-exempt capital <strong>in</strong>comes to today’s reportedtop <strong>in</strong>comes would be largely <strong>in</strong>sufficient toundo <strong>the</strong> observed fall. In <strong>the</strong> estimates <strong>of</strong>top shares for Norway (Rolf Aaberge <strong>and</strong>Atk<strong>in</strong>son 2010), a calculation has been made<strong>of</strong> <strong>in</strong>come <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> “full” return to stocks,but no systematic attempt has been made toimpute full capital <strong>in</strong>come on a comparablebasis over time <strong>and</strong> across countries. We viewthis as one <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> ma<strong>in</strong> shortcom<strong>in</strong>gs—probably<strong>the</strong> ma<strong>in</strong> shortcom<strong>in</strong>g—<strong>of</strong> our data set.As we shall see <strong>in</strong> sections below, this limits<strong>the</strong> extent to which one can use our data setto rigorously test <strong>the</strong> <strong>the</strong>oretical economicmechanisms at play.The treatment <strong>of</strong> capital ga<strong>in</strong>s <strong>and</strong> lossesalso differs across time <strong>and</strong> across countries.For a number <strong>of</strong> countries, series both <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g<strong>and</strong> exclud<strong>in</strong>g capital ga<strong>in</strong>s have beenproduced (see table 4). As shown <strong>in</strong> figure 7,<strong>the</strong> effects <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>clusion <strong>of</strong> capital ga<strong>in</strong>son <strong>the</strong> share <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> top percentile is <strong>of</strong>tensubstantial. In <strong>the</strong> case <strong>of</strong> Sweden, JesperRo<strong>in</strong>e <strong>and</strong> Daniel Waldenström (2008) notethat “over <strong>the</strong> past two decades <strong>the</strong> generalpicture turns out to depend crucially on25 Wolff <strong>and</strong> Zacharias (2009) use <strong>the</strong> Survey <strong>of</strong>Consumer F<strong>in</strong>ance <strong>and</strong> comb<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong>come <strong>and</strong> wealth datato estimate broader measures <strong>of</strong> capital <strong>in</strong>come s<strong>in</strong>ce 1982.how <strong>in</strong>come from capital ga<strong>in</strong>s is treated.If we <strong>in</strong>clude capital ga<strong>in</strong>s, Swedish <strong>in</strong>come<strong>in</strong>equality has <strong>in</strong>creased quite substantially;when exclud<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong>m, top <strong>in</strong>come shareshave <strong>in</strong>creased much less.” In all cases, onlyrealized capital ga<strong>in</strong>s are <strong>in</strong>cluded, if at all,<strong>in</strong> tax statistics <strong>and</strong> no <strong>in</strong>formation on accru<strong>in</strong>gcapital ga<strong>in</strong>s is available. Some accruedcapital ga<strong>in</strong>s are never realized, for example,when <strong>the</strong>re are step-up <strong>of</strong> basis provisions attime <strong>of</strong> death as <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> United States. 26F<strong>in</strong>ally, although <strong>the</strong> dist<strong>in</strong>ction betweencapital <strong>and</strong> labor <strong>in</strong>come is clear conceptually,it is <strong>of</strong>ten partly blurred <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> compositionaltax statistics. For example, realizedcapital ga<strong>in</strong>s <strong>of</strong> bus<strong>in</strong>ess owners <strong>of</strong>ten correspondto <strong>the</strong> sale <strong>of</strong> accumulated earn<strong>in</strong>gs<strong>of</strong> entrepreneurs <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong>ir firm, ra<strong>the</strong>r thanreturn on capital. Stock-option compensationsometimes appears as wage <strong>in</strong>come butsometimes as capital <strong>in</strong>come <strong>in</strong> tax statisticsdepend<strong>in</strong>g on <strong>the</strong> tax law.Income tax systems differ <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> extent<strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>ir provisions allow<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> deduction<strong>of</strong> such items as <strong>in</strong>terest paid, depreciation,pension contributions, alimony payments,<strong>and</strong> charitable contributions. Income fromwhich <strong>the</strong>se deductions have been subtractedis <strong>of</strong>ten referred to as “net <strong>in</strong>come.” (We arenot referr<strong>in</strong>g here to personal exemptions.)The aim is <strong>in</strong> general to measure gross<strong>in</strong>come before deductions, but this is notalways possible. The French estimates show<strong>in</strong>come after deduct<strong>in</strong>g employee socialsecurity contributions. In a number <strong>of</strong> countries,<strong>the</strong> earlier <strong>in</strong>come tax distributionsrefer to <strong>in</strong>come after <strong>the</strong>se deductions, but<strong>the</strong> later distributions refer to gross <strong>in</strong>come.In <strong>the</strong> United States, <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>come tax returnsprior to 1944 showed <strong>the</strong> distribution by26 Us<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> Survey <strong>of</strong> Consumer F<strong>in</strong>ances, Poterba<strong>and</strong> Scott Weisbenner (2001) estimate that, <strong>in</strong> 1998, capitalga<strong>in</strong>s unrealized at time <strong>of</strong> death were $42.8bn (table 10-8,p. 440), i.e., slightly less than 10 percent <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> $440bn <strong>of</strong>net realized capital ga<strong>in</strong>s reported on <strong>in</strong>dividual tax returns<strong>in</strong> 1998 (Piketty <strong>and</strong> Saez 2003).

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!