12.07.2015 Views

The Limits of Mathematics and NP Estimation in ... - Chichilnisky

The Limits of Mathematics and NP Estimation in ... - Chichilnisky

The Limits of Mathematics and NP Estimation in ... - Chichilnisky

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS
  • No tags were found...

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

54 Advances <strong>in</strong> Econometrics - <strong>The</strong>ory <strong>and</strong> Applications8 Will-be-set-by-IN-TECHthat many seasonal workers lose their job at the beg<strong>in</strong>n<strong>in</strong>g <strong>of</strong> each year <strong>and</strong> do not qualify forunemployment benefits.<strong>The</strong> bottom portion <strong>of</strong> the figure shows that the proportion <strong>of</strong> <strong>in</strong>dividuals engaged <strong>in</strong>government-sponsored tra<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g programs fluctuates considerably over time. A number <strong>of</strong>new welfare tra<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g programs have been implemented <strong>in</strong> 1989. Most <strong>of</strong> these programsaim at enhanc<strong>in</strong>g job search skills <strong>and</strong> usually last a few weeks. <strong>The</strong> large <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong>the proportion <strong>of</strong> welfare tra<strong>in</strong>ees co<strong>in</strong>cide with the implementation <strong>of</strong> these programs. Adramatic fall occurs towards the end <strong>of</strong> 1989 presumably l<strong>in</strong>ked to budgetary constra<strong>in</strong>tsassociated with the economic downturn <strong>of</strong> 1990. <strong>The</strong> proportion <strong>of</strong> participants steadily<strong>in</strong>creases thereafter <strong>and</strong> reaches its peak at the end <strong>of</strong> 1993. <strong>The</strong> proportion <strong>of</strong> UI tra<strong>in</strong>eesis relatively constant throughout the whole period, with the exception <strong>of</strong> 1992. Both the UItra<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g programs <strong>and</strong> JRP have relatively few participants at any po<strong>in</strong>t <strong>in</strong> time.<strong>The</strong> proportions <strong>of</strong> participants <strong>in</strong> the comb<strong>in</strong>ed programs hardly reach beyond 5% over thesample period. <strong>The</strong> fact that few <strong>in</strong>dividuals are engaged <strong>in</strong> formal tra<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g at any po<strong>in</strong>t <strong>in</strong>time is no <strong>in</strong>dication that tra<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g programs are <strong>in</strong>efficient or unattractive. Access to programsis <strong>of</strong>ten limited because <strong>of</strong> <strong>in</strong>sufficient resources. This lack <strong>of</strong> resources raises a fundamentalquestion: who gets selected <strong>in</strong>to tra<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g? To the econometrician, participation <strong>in</strong> a tra<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>gprogram is the result <strong>of</strong> two separate unidentifiable processes. First, the participant hasundertaken the necessary steps to take part <strong>in</strong> the program. Second, the program managerhas deemed the participant eligible. <strong>The</strong>se two processes are likely to be such that participantshave unobservable (to the econometrician) characteristics that are systematically differentfrom those <strong>of</strong> the non-participants. Fortunately, given the <strong>in</strong>formation at our disposal itis possible to devise estimators that, under very general assumptions, will yield unbiasedestimates <strong>of</strong> the programs’ impacts. <strong>The</strong>se estimators are presented <strong>in</strong> the next section.3. Model<strong>in</strong>g labour market transitions<strong>The</strong> labour market history <strong>of</strong> a given <strong>in</strong>dividual is represented by a sequence <strong>of</strong> n spells <strong>of</strong>various lengths <strong>in</strong> any <strong>of</strong> K (=7) states 11 . Let x t be the state <strong>in</strong> which an <strong>in</strong>dividual is observedto be at time t. <strong>The</strong> sequence starts at calendar time τ 0 = 0 when the <strong>in</strong>dividual is 16 years <strong>of</strong>age <strong>and</strong> ends at time τ e (τ e = December 1993). Figure 3 depicts a hypothetical sequence madeup <strong>of</strong> 3 spells <strong>of</strong> various length <strong>in</strong> 3 different states. As depicted, the <strong>in</strong>dividual is <strong>in</strong>itiallyobserved <strong>in</strong> the OLF state. He enters <strong>in</strong>to employment at time τ 1 <strong>and</strong> eventually moves <strong>in</strong>tounemployment at time τ 2 . At time τ e he is still <strong>in</strong> the midst <strong>of</strong> an unemployment spell.Let τ l denote the calendar time at which a spell <strong>in</strong> any given state ends. Each spell l (1 ≤l ≤ n) is thus delimited by the start time τ l−1 <strong>and</strong> the end time τ l (τ l > τ l−1 ). Let u l be theduration <strong>of</strong> spell l (u l = τ l − τ l−1 ). F<strong>in</strong>ally, let r denote a complete sequence from time 0 totime τ e :r =((u 1 , x τ1 ),...,(u n−1 , x τn−1 ), (u n ,0)),where u n = τ e − τ n−1 is the duration <strong>of</strong> the last spell. <strong>The</strong> last spell <strong>of</strong> each <strong>in</strong>dividual isright-censored s<strong>in</strong>ce τ n <strong>and</strong> x τn are not observed. On the other h<strong>and</strong>, the last spell musthave lasted at least τ n − τ n−1 units <strong>of</strong> time <strong>in</strong> state x τn−1 . Because x τn is not observed weconventionally fix x τn = 0.11 See Fougère & Kamionka (2008) for a more general presentation <strong>of</strong> the econometrics <strong>of</strong> transitionmodels.

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!