13.07.2015 Views

PRIVATIZATION Privatization in Malaysia, Regulation, rent-seeking and policy failure

PRIVATIZATION Privatization in Malaysia, Regulation, rent-seeking and policy failure

PRIVATIZATION Privatization in Malaysia, Regulation, rent-seeking and policy failure

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

32 <strong>Privatization</strong>, <strong>rent</strong>s <strong>and</strong> <strong>rent</strong>-seek<strong>in</strong>gare faced with the problem of <strong>in</strong>competent (non-capitalist) c<strong>and</strong>idates whoare also harder to discipl<strong>in</strong>e.As the state’s connection with society <strong>in</strong> develop<strong>in</strong>g countries may not beproduction-oriented alliances but rather with unproductive ‘non-capitalist’classes created <strong>and</strong> brought together by the colonial legacy <strong>and</strong> struggle for<strong>in</strong>dependence, these groups have had to be accommodated. These groupshave been variously described as ‘a well-educated but economicallyunproductive professional class’ (Pempel 1999: 169–170), the ‘educatedsalaried middle classes’ (Alavi, H. 1982: 299), <strong>and</strong> the <strong>in</strong>termediate class leftbeh<strong>in</strong>d <strong>in</strong> the development process (Khan 1998: 19), whose political role isof considerable importance, organiz<strong>in</strong>g resistance <strong>and</strong> develop<strong>in</strong>g ways to‘modify certa<strong>in</strong> market outcomes “politically”’ (Alavi, H. 1982: 299; Khan1998: 19). State capacity therefore not only depends on the state’s relationshipwith segments of capital but also on political constra<strong>in</strong>ts posed by othergroups <strong>in</strong> society outside the ‘developmental alliance’.Furthermore, the state–society relationship <strong>in</strong> develop<strong>in</strong>g countries is notformalized or ‘<strong>in</strong>stitutionalized’ (as has been argued by some <strong>in</strong> the SouthKorean case [e.g. see Evans 1994]) but personalized, usually between patrons<strong>and</strong> clients. Patron–client relationships are repeated relationships of exchangebetween specific patrons <strong>and</strong> their clients. The nature of this relationship (<strong>in</strong>terms of how it is likely to <strong>in</strong>fluence economic decisions) depends on theobjectives <strong>and</strong> ideologies of the patrons <strong>and</strong> clients; the number of potentialclients <strong>and</strong> their degree of organization; the homogeneity of clients; <strong>and</strong> the<strong>in</strong>stitutions through which patrons <strong>and</strong> clients <strong>in</strong>teract, <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g the degreeof fragmentation of <strong>in</strong>stitutions (Khan 1998: 23–26). More critically, therelative power of patrons <strong>and</strong> clients can determ<strong>in</strong>e how resources are allocated.In South Korea, it was possible for the state to extract the maximumeconomic payoff while ensur<strong>in</strong>g that resource allocation was efficient becauseclients of the state both <strong>in</strong> the bus<strong>in</strong>ess sector <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong> politics were weak.Inefficient clients could not defend themselves <strong>and</strong> the state had no <strong>in</strong>terest <strong>in</strong>defend<strong>in</strong>g them.However, where the patron is politically weak, <strong>in</strong>efficient clients may easilysurvive because clients <strong>in</strong> this context may be offer<strong>in</strong>g political support (orthe absence of political opposition) rather than an economic payoff. Thispolitical corruption may be necessary to ensure stability but can also begrowth-reduc<strong>in</strong>g. This depends <strong>in</strong> part on the degree of centralization, withcentralized corruption be<strong>in</strong>g potentially less harmful (Bardhan 1997; also seeShleifer <strong>and</strong> Vishny 1993) as reflected <strong>in</strong> the diffe<strong>rent</strong> impact of corruptionon economic growth <strong>in</strong> South Korea <strong>and</strong> South Asia (e.g. see Khan 1998).Patron–client networks <strong>in</strong> India <strong>and</strong> Pakistan reveal the substantial politicalpower of clients from <strong>in</strong>termediate ‘non-capitalist’ classes whose necessaryaccommodation made it more difficult for the state to reallocate <strong>rent</strong>s moreefficiently. This partly expla<strong>in</strong>s the persistence of <strong>in</strong>efficient <strong>rent</strong>s <strong>in</strong> theIndian subcont<strong>in</strong>ent (Khan 1998, undated).

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!