01.09.2015 Views

A Path to Prosperity New Directions for African Livestock

GALVmed Impetus Strategy Paper

GALVmed Impetus Strategy Paper

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS
  • No tags were found...

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

6.3 Contract Farming<br />

In<strong>for</strong>mal, traditional markets <strong>for</strong> lives<strong>to</strong>ck products<br />

are still dominant in most of SSA. For example, 90%<br />

of Ghana’s beef supply is channelled through the<br />

in<strong>for</strong>mal markets. Smallholders can compete in<br />

in<strong>for</strong>mal or ‘spot’ markets because they have lower<br />

quality standards and the markets don’t depend on<br />

regular supply from a given producer. However, rising<br />

incomes and expectations of urban consumers<br />

promote more sophisticated and <strong>for</strong>mal market<br />

arrangements. This is symbolised by the growth of<br />

supermarkets across the developing world. Though<br />

Africa lags behind other regions, supermarkets and<br />

the value chains they represent are slowly becoming<br />

a reality. In the early 2000s, supermarkets had<br />

50–60% of the market in Latin America, 10–30% in<br />

S.E. Asia and increasing market share in eastern and<br />

southern Africa. In Kenya, <strong>for</strong> example, they had a<br />

20% share of the processed food market 127 . These<br />

figures are now probably higher.<br />

As markets develop they expect four key requirements<br />

that all involve higher costs per unit of product <strong>for</strong><br />

small farmers and potentially allow larger<br />

producers <strong>to</strong> capture the market. These are:<br />

> Quality and safety standards, which often<br />

require on-farm investments;<br />

> Uni<strong>for</strong>mity of the product, requiring investments<br />

in breeding, feeding, and veterinary health;<br />

> Reliability of supply, which requires product<br />

specialization and/or higher level of production; and<br />

> Verifiability of origin, which requires traceability<br />

systems 128 .<br />

Of course, not all small farmers will be able <strong>to</strong><br />

meet the requirements of a <strong>for</strong>malised market and<br />

will either drop out of farming or continue supplying<br />

in<strong>for</strong>mal local markets. In Brazil in the 1990s<br />

supermarketisation was directly linked <strong>to</strong> the exit of<br />

small dairy farmers. Sixty thousand farmers ceased<br />

production in ten years and the average farm size<br />

increased by 55%, with similar patterns in Argentina<br />

and Chile 129 . Whilst Africa is still a long way from<br />

value chains being dominated by supermarkets,<br />

policy makers and agri-business do need <strong>to</strong><br />

determine how <strong>to</strong> assist those small farmers who<br />

are willing and capable of meeting higher standards<br />

and how <strong>to</strong> create the jobs <strong>for</strong> those who are not.<br />

Experience from the horticultural sec<strong>to</strong>r suggests<br />

small <strong>African</strong> farmers are able <strong>to</strong> meet higher<br />

standards and thrive when supported <strong>to</strong> do so.<br />

The three ways <strong>for</strong> supporting small farmers<br />

commonly cited are first, strengthening cooperative<br />

action between farmers, secondly, contract farming<br />

and thirdly, strengthening farmers associations.<br />

Cooperative farming systems can be very successful.<br />

For example: the National Dairy Development Board<br />

in India; Fonterra, the world's largest exporter of<br />

dairy products and owned by 13000 <strong>New</strong> Zealand<br />

dairy farmers; Land O’Lakes, the USA’s second<br />

largest cooperative serving 300,000 farmers and the<br />

Development Foundation of Turkey (TKV) working<br />

with 2500 broiler producers. However, these tend <strong>to</strong><br />

be exceptions. Most cooperatives are unable <strong>to</strong><br />

compete with private companies 130 and their<br />

establishment is both complex and relatively slow.<br />

Contract farming appears <strong>to</strong> offer more potential and<br />

there is evidence <strong>to</strong> suggest that in the developing<br />

world contract farmers have, in most cases, higher<br />

profits per unit of output than independent farmers<br />

(both large and small). Contract farming can<br />

incorporate smallholders in high-value supply chains<br />

that require specialized inputs and sell <strong>to</strong> markets<br />

<strong>for</strong> specialized outputs. The three main types of<br />

contract farming have been described by Minot 131 as:<br />

1 Market-specification contracts – where the<br />

contract involves an exchange of technical and<br />

market in<strong>for</strong>mation about the product quality<br />

required, timing and prices <strong>for</strong> specified markets.<br />

2 Management-providing contracts – where the<br />

farmer is assisted in terms of least-cost<br />

production practices <strong>to</strong> attain higher quality and<br />

control the timing of output. The contrac<strong>to</strong>r<br />

recoups the costs of extension provided from the<br />

proceeds of marketing a higher-quality product.<br />

3 Resource-providing contracts – where credit,<br />

inputs and/or agricultural services are provided<br />

by the contrac<strong>to</strong>r who then recoups outlay<br />

through marketing of the product.<br />

Which type of contract is needed will vary by value<br />

chain and depend upon the circumstances of the<br />

farmers. While vertically integrated systems that<br />

depend on contracts sound like an excellent solution<br />

<strong>to</strong> improving market access and the capacity of small<br />

lives<strong>to</strong>ck farmers, there are un<strong>for</strong>tunately very few<br />

examples of them functioning in SSA. (Box 7 provides<br />

some examples of successful contract farming<br />

arrangements). This lack of examples is perhaps<br />

related <strong>to</strong> the fact that contract farming requires<br />

effective en<strong>for</strong>cement of a clear legal framework and<br />

this is a problem in many SSA countries. Interestingly,<br />

contract farming is the norm in the developed world<br />

<strong>for</strong> poultry and pork value chains. How <strong>to</strong> develop<br />

contract farming operations in SSA is a key challenge.<br />

The Impetus Strategy Paper I Page 45

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!