25.01.2013 Views

Equilibrium Growth, Inflation, and Bond Yields - Duke University's ...

Equilibrium Growth, Inflation, and Bond Yields - Duke University's ...

Equilibrium Growth, Inflation, and Bond Yields - Duke University's ...

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

nominal yield curve <strong>and</strong> sizeable term spread. 29<br />

I first begin with a discussion of the equilibrium inflation <strong>and</strong> growth dynamics. Note that in the<br />

bottom row of Figure 1 the benchmark model (ENDO 1) replicates the negative low-frequency patterns in<br />

consumption growth <strong>and</strong> inflation from the data. As before, the low-frequency component is identified using<br />

a b<strong>and</strong>pass filter, where the b<strong>and</strong>width is from 32 to 200 quarters. Indeed, Table 10 shows that the ENDO 1<br />

closely matches low-frequency correlations between macro growth rates <strong>and</strong> inflation. Furthermore, expected<br />

consumption growth <strong>and</strong> expected inflation are strongly negatively correlated. To underst<strong>and</strong> the mechanics<br />

behind these endogenous long-run dynamics, it is instructive to look at the impulse response functions from<br />

Figure 6. First, I will focus on the IRFs for ENDO 1 which correspond to the solid lines. When a good<br />

productivity shock is realized, expected growth rates, including consumption growth, increase persistently<br />

as discussed above. Now, I will also show that expected inflation declines persistently in response to a good<br />

productivity shock. Recall from Section 3, inflation depends on positively on the wage to capital ratio <strong>and</strong><br />

labor hours worked, <strong>and</strong> negatively on the productivity shock <strong>and</strong> the R&D stock to physical capital stock<br />

ratio:<br />

where γ1 = ν−1<br />

φR > 0, γ2 = β∆Y<br />

�πt = γ1 �mct + γ2Et[�πt+1]<br />

�mct = �wt + α � lt − (1 − α)�at − (1 − α)�nt<br />

1 1− ψ<br />

ss<br />

> 0, <strong>and</strong> lowercase tilde variables denote log deviations from the steady-<br />

state. As discussed above, �wt <strong>and</strong> � lt increase in response to an increase in �at. In addition, because the firm<br />

has very high incentives to take advantage of the good shock to increase long-run growth prospects, the stock<br />

of R&D increases more relative to the increase in physical capital. Thus, �nt also increases. Quantitatively,<br />

the increase in the terms (1 − α)�at <strong>and</strong> (1 − α)�nt dominates the increase in �wt <strong>and</strong> α � lt, so that marginal<br />

costs, <strong>and</strong> therefore inflation declines. In sum, the productivity shock drives a strong negative relationship<br />

between expected consumption growth <strong>and</strong> expected inflation. Moreover, these dynamics are reflected in<br />

asset markets by an upward sloping yield curve <strong>and</strong> sizeable term spread.<br />

Importantly, there is strong empirical support for these model-implied inflation-growth dynamics. Barsky<br />

<strong>and</strong> Sims (2010) <strong>and</strong> Kurmann <strong>and</strong> Otrok (2011) show in a VAR that a positive shock to expected produc-<br />

tivity growth (“news shock”) leads to large <strong>and</strong> persistent decline in inflation. In the benchmark growth<br />

model, fluctuations to expected productivity growth are driven by R&D rates. Specifically, in the bench-<br />

mark growth model, the expected productivity growth component is the growth rate of the stock of R&D.<br />

As discussed above, a persistent increase in R&D during good times lowers marginal costs <strong>and</strong> inflation per-<br />

29 Piazzesi <strong>and</strong> Schneider (2006) <strong>and</strong> Bansal <strong>and</strong> Shaliastovich (2010) highlight this point in endowment economy<br />

setups where inflation <strong>and</strong> consumption growth are exogenously specified <strong>and</strong> assumed to be negatively correlated.<br />

Furthermore, they find strong empirical evidence for this negative relationship.<br />

22

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!