27.11.2014 Views

State of World Fisheries and Aquaculture 2004 - Library

State of World Fisheries and Aquaculture 2004 - Library

State of World Fisheries and Aquaculture 2004 - Library

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

Highlights <strong>of</strong> special FAO studies<br />

129<br />

development <strong>of</strong> domestic fishing fleets. These were long-lasting <strong>and</strong>, by the early<br />

1990s, Canada was forced to close its major Atlantic cod fisheries to commercial fishing<br />

because the stocks had been decimated. Similarly, by 1999, one-third <strong>of</strong> the stocks<br />

controlled by the United <strong>State</strong>s Government whose status was known were considered<br />

to have been overfished. Subsidies no doubt played their role in these events.<br />

JUSTIFICATION AND HISTORY<br />

There are at least three potential justifications for subsidies. First, there is the infant<br />

industry concept wherein the government must provide seed capital if a domestic<br />

industry is to take hold in the face <strong>of</strong> existing foreign competition. Second, a large <strong>and</strong><br />

important firm may encounter temporary financial difficulties which, if the firm went<br />

out <strong>of</strong> business, could spill over <strong>and</strong> damage other, healthy, aspects <strong>of</strong> the economy.<br />

By temporarily <strong>of</strong>fering subsidy protection, the government might protect the entire<br />

economy. Third, subsidies can be used to encourage firms to behave in environmentally<br />

friendly ways.<br />

Forty years ago, subsidies were generally seen as being socially useful, largely under<br />

the infant industry argument. With the passage <strong>of</strong> years, <strong>and</strong> changing views <strong>of</strong> the<br />

role <strong>of</strong> government in the economy, subsidies are less <strong>of</strong>ten seen as socially useful<br />

– although many find the environmental justification <strong>of</strong> subsidies to be compelling.<br />

Subsidies have to be judged in the social context in which they are embedded. Will<br />

they accomplish their purpose? If they do ultimately accomplish their purpose, will it<br />

be possible to abolish them before the point at which they may start to do harm? Are<br />

there alternative ways for the government to accomplish its goals?<br />

Regardless <strong>of</strong> whether these questions have been asked <strong>and</strong> suitably answered in<br />

specific cases, the history <strong>of</strong> fishery subsidies is a long one, as will be seen from the<br />

following examples.<br />

Within 20 years <strong>of</strong> the establishment <strong>of</strong> the Massachusetts colony in 1620, fishermen<br />

were being subsidized by exemptions from military duty <strong>and</strong> from certain taxes. In the<br />

seventeenth century, Engl<strong>and</strong> granted monopolies to stimulate the fisheries <strong>of</strong> what<br />

is now Atlantic Canada. In the middle <strong>of</strong> the nineteenth century, Norway engaged<br />

scientists to investigate fluctuations in fish catches, marking the beginning <strong>of</strong> a long<br />

programme <strong>of</strong> government support to Norwegian fisheries. The modernization <strong>of</strong><br />

Icel<strong>and</strong>ic fisheries received a stimulus when, towards the end <strong>of</strong> the nineteenth century,<br />

a government bank extended loans for the purchase <strong>of</strong> fishing vessels. Peru, in the<br />

early 1970s, introduced a plan to develop its fisheries for the purpose <strong>of</strong> supplying fresh<br />

<strong>and</strong> frozen fish products to the domestic market. This plan included a governmentfinanced<br />

investment programme in fisheries infrastructure <strong>and</strong> equipment. In the 15<br />

years following 1960, the Chilean Government used a subsidy programme <strong>of</strong> income<br />

tax <strong>and</strong> import duty exemptions to develop its fisheries. For a quarter <strong>of</strong> a century<br />

beginning in the mid-1960s, Brazil developed its fisheries through a variety <strong>of</strong> tax<br />

exemptions. The list can go on <strong>and</strong> on, including subsidies in developed <strong>and</strong> developing<br />

countries, <strong>and</strong> from hundreds <strong>of</strong> years ago to this day.<br />

MEASUREMENT OF SUBSIDIES<br />

The measurement <strong>of</strong> subsidies has been complicated by the diversity <strong>of</strong> subsidy<br />

definitions, a lack <strong>of</strong> data <strong>and</strong>, when international bodies have undertaken subsidy<br />

measurements, inconsistencies generated by the variety <strong>of</strong> concepts the individual<br />

countries are prepared to consider as subsidies. When subsidies are measured, the cost<br />

to government <strong>of</strong> financial transfers, or <strong>of</strong> waived receipts, usually provides the basis<br />

for the computations. There have been several major attempts to measure fishery<br />

subsidies in this way; in particular, a book on the subject by M. Milazzo published by<br />

the <strong>World</strong> Bank is the seminal work in the field. 84 In addition, the OECD has compiled<br />

<strong>and</strong> published a list, by country, <strong>of</strong> government financial transfers to the fishing<br />

84<br />

M. Milazzo. 1998. Subsidies in world fisheries: a re-examination. Washington, DC, <strong>World</strong> Bank.

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!