27.01.2015 Views

Handbook on Contemporary Austrian Economics

Handbook on Contemporary Austrian Economics

Handbook on Contemporary Austrian Economics

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

M<strong>on</strong>ey is n<strong>on</strong>-neutral 117<br />

or less the same as they were before." A comm<strong>on</strong> explanati<strong>on</strong> for m<strong>on</strong>ey<br />

illusi<strong>on</strong> stems from the costs of obtaining informati<strong>on</strong>. If nominal prices<br />

change slowly and by relatively small amounts, what incentives exist for<br />

people to collect informati<strong>on</strong> about the inflati<strong>on</strong> adjusted prices Similarly,<br />

people often fail to collect informati<strong>on</strong> about the source of price changes.<br />

Whether supply or demand changed because of a real or nominal change<br />

involves costs that people often view as relatively high. In most costs, not<br />

knowing the real price of a good has very little impact <strong>on</strong> behavior.<br />

An alternative <strong>Austrian</strong> explanati<strong>on</strong> exists but has been little explored.<br />

Hayek's The Sensory Order (1952) argues that people's percepti<strong>on</strong>s evolve<br />

in resp<strong>on</strong>se to repeated interacti<strong>on</strong> with the external envir<strong>on</strong>ment. If<br />

people operate within an envir<strong>on</strong>ment of nominal prices (as they do), they<br />

will think in nominal terms. It should not be surprising that they c<strong>on</strong>fuse<br />

real and nominal variables as their minds have evolved to operate within<br />

the nominal world. Future research may examine the relati<strong>on</strong>ship between<br />

Hayek's psychological writings and their relati<strong>on</strong>ship to the m<strong>on</strong>etary<br />

ec<strong>on</strong>omy.<br />

8.3.4 Sticky prices and l<strong>on</strong>g-term c<strong>on</strong>tracts<br />

For m<strong>on</strong>ey to have neutral effects, wages and prices must adjust to<br />

changing demand and supply c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s. If prices resp<strong>on</strong>d to changes in<br />

the m<strong>on</strong>etary c<strong>on</strong>tracti<strong>on</strong> or expansi<strong>on</strong>, m<strong>on</strong>ey is neutral. Yet, in many<br />

markets, prices do not adjust immediately to new c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s. They remain<br />

the same after the m<strong>on</strong>etary authority has adopted a course of acti<strong>on</strong> that<br />

either reduces or increases the m<strong>on</strong>ey supply. A number of reas<strong>on</strong>s have<br />

been posited to explain the lag in changing prices after a change in the<br />

m<strong>on</strong>ey supply.<br />

L<strong>on</strong>g-term c<strong>on</strong>tracting limits the neutrality of m<strong>on</strong>ey in the short run.<br />

Hayek (1935, p. 131) wrote that "the existence of a generally used medium<br />

of exchange will always lead to the existence of l<strong>on</strong>g-term c<strong>on</strong>tracts in<br />

terms of this medium of exchange, which will have been c<strong>on</strong>cluded in the<br />

expectati<strong>on</strong> of a certain future price level." Individuals guess as to what<br />

future prices will be. Sometimes they correctly guess future prices and<br />

sometimes they do not. They negotiate c<strong>on</strong>tracts in order to minimize<br />

uncertainty about the future. When they guess wr<strong>on</strong>g about the future,<br />

m<strong>on</strong>ey has a n<strong>on</strong>-neutral effect. For example, wage c<strong>on</strong>tracts are denominated<br />

in nominal terms. If actual inflati<strong>on</strong> exceeds expected inflati<strong>on</strong>, then<br />

the real wage falls. If the workers realized their real wages have fallen, they<br />

may resp<strong>on</strong>d by reducing productivity.<br />

New Keynesian models formalized and extended the sources of price<br />

stickiness. Menu costs offered a simple, example. When price changes<br />

are small, it may be too costly to print up new menus. The benefits from

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!