23.03.2013 Views

Constraints to Increasing Agricultural Productivity in Nigeria: A Review

Constraints to Increasing Agricultural Productivity in Nigeria: A Review

Constraints to Increasing Agricultural Productivity in Nigeria: A Review

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

foster<strong>in</strong>g many other economic activities, <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>frastructural development, creation of<br />

new <strong>in</strong>stitutions and expansion of exist<strong>in</strong>g ones, and importation of all k<strong>in</strong>ds of consumer<br />

goods. The appreciation <strong>in</strong> the value of the naira (Dutch disease) favored these<br />

developments, but tradable agricultural commodities did not experience similar growth.<br />

The share of the oil sec<strong>to</strong>r <strong>in</strong> the <strong>to</strong>tal value of exports, which was under 60 percent <strong>in</strong> 1970,<br />

rose <strong>to</strong> over 90 percent after 1973. The non-oil exports decl<strong>in</strong>ed from about 30 percent <strong>in</strong><br />

1970 <strong>to</strong> less than 10 percent by 1980 (Ojo 1992). The unprecedented <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> public<br />

expenditure placed the <strong>Nigeria</strong>n economy under severe <strong>in</strong>flationary pressure. The<br />

emergence of a dom<strong>in</strong>ant oil sec<strong>to</strong>r was accompanied by the gradual lessen<strong>in</strong>g of<br />

<strong>in</strong>ternational competitiveness of the agricultural export subsec<strong>to</strong>r, aris<strong>in</strong>g from local currency<br />

appreciation, <strong>in</strong>adequate pric<strong>in</strong>g policies (especially fixed producer prices relative <strong>to</strong><br />

earn<strong>in</strong>gs from the world market), and the general neglect of the rural sec<strong>to</strong>r.<br />

Oil export earn<strong>in</strong>gs collapsed <strong>in</strong> the early 1980s from a peak of $24.9 billion <strong>in</strong> 1980 <strong>to</strong> $5.2<br />

billion <strong>in</strong> 1986 (Ojo 1992). The exchange-rate adjustments <strong>in</strong> many African countries,<br />

<strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g <strong>Nigeria</strong> s<strong>in</strong>ce the 1980s, were <strong>in</strong> response <strong>to</strong> widespread balance of payments<br />

problems and the consequent need <strong>to</strong> correct the seem<strong>in</strong>gly <strong>in</strong>tractable macroeconomic<br />

dis<strong>to</strong>rtions. However, agriculture rema<strong>in</strong>ed relevant <strong>to</strong> <strong>Nigeria</strong>’s food and raw materials<br />

supplies, rural employment, and general price stability (Phillip 1996).<br />

<strong>Agricultural</strong> Sec<strong>to</strong>r Policies <strong>in</strong> <strong>Nigeria</strong><br />

The roles of the <strong>Nigeria</strong>n agricultural sec<strong>to</strong>r, accord<strong>in</strong>g <strong>to</strong> the <strong>Nigeria</strong>n <strong>Agricultural</strong> Policy<br />

document (FDA/MANR 1988, FDA/MARD 2001), <strong>in</strong>clude provision of food for the grow<strong>in</strong>g<br />

population, foreign exchange earn<strong>in</strong>gs, employ<strong>in</strong>g a significant part of the labor force, and<br />

provid<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>come for farm<strong>in</strong>g households. To atta<strong>in</strong> agricultural-sec<strong>to</strong>r goals, several policies<br />

were formulated and implemented dur<strong>in</strong>g the post-<strong>in</strong>dependence years. Here we summarize<br />

some key policies <strong>to</strong> better understand their l<strong>in</strong>kages <strong>to</strong> the productivity constra<strong>in</strong>ts identified<br />

later <strong>in</strong> this review.<br />

From 1970–85, capital for agricultural production and post-harvest activities came ma<strong>in</strong>ly<br />

from the government’s budgetary allocations and secondarily from exist<strong>in</strong>g lend<strong>in</strong>g<br />

<strong>in</strong>stitutions. However, as observed by Ojo and Akanji (1996), “from the first through the<br />

fourth National Development Plans, government spent less than 10 percent of its <strong>to</strong>tal capital<br />

expenditures on agriculture, which contributed more than 60 percent of the GDP.” And, with<br />

the poorly developed capital markets, farmers’ credit dur<strong>in</strong>g the period came mostly from<br />

<strong>in</strong>formal sources at prohibitive <strong>in</strong>terest rates. <strong>Agricultural</strong> production, productivity, and postharvest<br />

operations were low and little affected by improved technologies.<br />

The ma<strong>in</strong> monetary policy <strong>in</strong>struments used before 1985 <strong>in</strong>cluded selective credit controls,<br />

credit ceil<strong>in</strong>gs, and <strong>in</strong>terest rate controls. Beg<strong>in</strong>n<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> 1972, commercial and merchant<br />

banks were mandated <strong>to</strong> provide a prescribed m<strong>in</strong>imum percentage of their <strong>to</strong>tal loans <strong>to</strong><br />

agriculture. These manda<strong>to</strong>ry credit allocations <strong>to</strong> agriculture have received mixed reviews.<br />

Babalola and Odoko (1996) noted that manda<strong>to</strong>ry credit allocation was effective only <strong>to</strong> the<br />

extent that it provided some alternative <strong>to</strong> scarce and poorly developed sources of<br />

agricultural funds. The authors also argued that manda<strong>to</strong>ry credit allocation is <strong>in</strong>consistent<br />

with f<strong>in</strong>ancial-sec<strong>to</strong>r reform and tends <strong>to</strong> promote credit misallocation. In their study, Balogun<br />

and Otu (1991) further noted that “both commercial and merchant banks consistently lent<br />

short of the prescribed limits under the credit allocation policy.” This policy was abolished <strong>in</strong><br />

late 1996.<br />

Before the <strong>in</strong>troduction of the Structural Adjustment Programme (SAP) <strong>in</strong> 1986, agricultural<br />

lend<strong>in</strong>g rates were largely concessional or subsidized. The 1970s witnessed very low<br />

<strong>in</strong>terest rates that could not encourage the development of money or capital markets. No<br />

12

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!