21.01.2014 Views

… and the Pursuit of Happiness - Institute of Economic Affairs

… and the Pursuit of Happiness - Institute of Economic Affairs

… and the Pursuit of Happiness - Institute of Economic Affairs

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

<strong>…</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> pursuit <strong>of</strong> happiness<br />

wellbeing <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> size <strong>of</strong> government<br />

<strong>and</strong> policy costs is more possible <strong>and</strong> specific problems can be<br />

addressed that are not within <strong>the</strong> effective reach <strong>of</strong> national<br />

policies. One would <strong>the</strong>refore expect that <strong>the</strong> costs (benefits) <strong>of</strong><br />

government spending <strong>and</strong> interventions are larger with more<br />

(less) centralised decision authority.<br />

One <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> few papers to distinguish between centralised <strong>and</strong><br />

decentralised decision-making, Bjørnskov et al. (2008b: 150),<br />

concludes that ‘Local autonomy, however, increases well-being<br />

only ins<strong>of</strong>ar as it neutralizes <strong>the</strong> detrimental impact <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> government<br />

sector.’ In o<strong>the</strong>r words, decentralised governments are likely<br />

to make decisions <strong>and</strong> implement policies that are, on average,<br />

neutral with respect to <strong>the</strong> wellbeing <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>ir citizens. Centralising<br />

political decision-making, on <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r h<strong>and</strong>, makes it more likely<br />

that <strong>the</strong> size <strong>and</strong> scope <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> public sector grows to <strong>the</strong> extent <strong>of</strong><br />

being significantly detrimental to wellbeing (cf. Frey, 2008).<br />

The o<strong>the</strong>r main question is whe<strong>the</strong>r economic development<br />

increases national wellbeing. This topic is covered by Sacks,<br />

Stevenson <strong>and</strong> Wolfers (in this volume), who show that economic<br />

growth leads to higher subjective wellbeing in <strong>the</strong> long run. One<br />

<strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> main drivers <strong>of</strong> growth, economic globalisation, also causes<br />

higher levels <strong>of</strong> subjective wellbeing over <strong>and</strong> above its effects on<br />

growth (cf. Bjørnskov et al., 2008a; Tsai, 2009).<br />

At <strong>the</strong> individual level, people tend to get used to being richer<br />

– at least to some extent – when national wealth has reached<br />

a relatively moderate level. Likewise, most people adjust <strong>the</strong>ir<br />

expectations somewhat downwards when <strong>the</strong>y are consistently<br />

disappointed (Stutzer, 2004; Dolan et al., 2008). As such,<br />

reductions in private consumption resulting from higher taxes<br />

to finance government spending may in principle cause only a<br />

temporary reduction in wellbeing until individual expectations<br />

<strong>and</strong> aspirations have adjusted. In practice, however, Di Tella et al.<br />

(2003) show that people are not likely to adjust <strong>the</strong>ir expectations<br />

fully. Because <strong>of</strong> this, economic growth is likely to lead to higher<br />

wellbeing overall.<br />

The government sector <strong>and</strong> its active role in society could thus<br />

cause losses <strong>of</strong> happiness in <strong>the</strong> long run because <strong>of</strong> its effect on<br />

economic growth. Activist government policies <strong>and</strong> a growing<br />

public sector are likely to undermine both growth <strong>and</strong> globalisation<br />

(e.g. Fölster <strong>and</strong> Henrekson, 2001; Bergh <strong>and</strong> Henrekson,<br />

2011), <strong>and</strong> thus slow down <strong>the</strong> already slow trend towards greater<br />

wellbeing. Given this, <strong>the</strong> apparently popular case for active<br />

government involvement in increasing wellbeing seems misdirected.<br />

As noted above, a number <strong>of</strong> studies find no basis for <strong>the</strong><br />

claim that government spending is positively associated with<br />

happiness. High government spending instead tends to reduce<br />

growth <strong>and</strong> may also be harmful to o<strong>the</strong>r factors contributing to<br />

happiness.<br />

In addition, <strong>the</strong> potentially positive effects <strong>of</strong> material<br />

improvements may be less likely to be visible in <strong>the</strong> wellbeing <strong>of</strong><br />

countries. As a sizeable share <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> population provides answers<br />

that are close to <strong>the</strong> maximum happiness level in survey questions,<br />

<strong>the</strong> inability to place one’s assessment <strong>of</strong> wellbeing higher<br />

than <strong>the</strong> top category <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> questionnaire constrains <strong>the</strong> surveys<br />

at <strong>the</strong> top end, <strong>the</strong>reby making it more difficult to measure <strong>the</strong><br />

real effects <strong>of</strong> improvements within <strong>the</strong> group <strong>of</strong> countries that<br />

already has high levels <strong>of</strong> wellbeing (see Ormerod <strong>and</strong> Johns,<br />

2007; Stevenson <strong>and</strong> Wolfers, 2008). The real effects <strong>of</strong> government<br />

spending in rich democracies may thus be underestimated.<br />

170 171

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!