30.05.2014 Views

Option-Implied Currency Risk Premia - Princeton University

Option-Implied Currency Risk Premia - Princeton University

Option-Implied Currency Risk Premia - Princeton University

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

(Specification I) reproduces the relation exactly, with a coefficient estimate of -0.46 (t-stat: -3.06). In contrast,<br />

once loadings have been perturbed by Ψ ∗ – in order to match the historical point estimate of the mean return on<br />

the empirical factor mimicking portfolio for the HML F X factor – the relation becomes statistically insignificant,<br />

with a point estimate of -0.03 (t-stat: -0.20).<br />

The intuition from skewness regressions is similar in spirit. In the data, the relation between the optionimplied<br />

skewness and the interest rate differential is weakly negative, with a point estimate between -0.89 (t-stat:<br />

-1.66) and -1.21 (t-stat: -1.81). Unsurprisingly, the value of the coefficient here is more sensitive to the details<br />

of the implied volatility extrapolation scheme used to compute the value of the option-implied skewness. Our<br />

preferred calibration produces a noticeably stronger link, with a point estimate of -6.66 (t-stat: -3.35). This link<br />

is strengthened even further once the model is forced to match historical risk premia (Ψ ∗ > 0), raising the point<br />

estimate to -12.41 (t-stat: -6.20). Once again, we find that inducing strong covariation between loadings and<br />

interest rate differentials, pushes the relation between model-implied exchange rate moments and interest rate<br />

differentials further away from that observed in the data.<br />

4.2 Do global factor loadings depend on Y i<br />

t ?<br />

Within the model, the dynamics of FX option prices and interest rates, (5), are driven by the global and<br />

country-specific state variables. In Panel B of Table VI, we examine the existence of this relationship by regressing<br />

the change in the one-month interest rate onto terms governing the model-implied change, ∆ ( −k g [ ] )<br />

t −ξ<br />

i<br />

t · Zt<br />

and ∆ ( −kt i [−1] · Yt<br />

i )<br />

. Notice that while this regression is the closest proxy to our model, it suffers from omitted<br />

variable bias due to the absence of an empirical proxy for α i t. We find that the country-level regressions<br />

consistently point to the absence of a link between interest rates and the state variables extracted from foreign exchange<br />

options. The p-values of the joint test that the coefficients on the model-implied variables are equal to one<br />

strongly rejects the model within each country. This negative result leaves open the possibility that linking global<br />

factor loadings to the Y i<br />

t<br />

state variables directly, rather than interest rate differential, may generate the desired<br />

increase in risk premia for models with time-varying loadings. As mentioned earlier, this type of parametrization<br />

is explicitly built into the “unrestricted” model of Lustig, et al. (2011).<br />

We repeat the calibration of our preferred model specification, allowing global factor loadings to be tied<br />

to local state variable dynamics via ξt<br />

i = ξ i − ˜Ψ t · (Y<br />

t i − Yt<br />

US )<br />

. Similar to the parametrization based on<br />

interest rate differentials, this expression normalizes the U.S. loading to equal ξ US at each point in time, which<br />

is set equal to one. Repeating the calibration of our preferred specification, we find that the mean value of<br />

˜Ψ t in the time series is -0.37 (t-stat: -1.84). The RMSE of the option fitted error is 1.05, which is slightly<br />

35

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!