14.09.2015 Views

Business Removing

Doing Business in 2005 -- Removing Obstacles to Growth

Doing Business in 2005 -- Removing Obstacles to Growth

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS
  • No tags were found...

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

ENFORCING CONTRACTS 65<br />

Two types of reform have worked. First, in Finland,<br />

Ireland and Sweden, a state enforcement authority collects<br />

all debt, including what is due in taxes. Armenia, Estonia<br />

and Latvia recently adopted a similar system. The<br />

second option is to privatize the enforcement process.<br />

In France, a private enforcement specialist, huissier de<br />

justice, collects on all private claims. 21 Belgium and the<br />

Netherlands also have private enforcement, as do many<br />

former French colonies, such as Algeria and Benin. Inspired<br />

by the French example, Hungary, Poland, Scotland<br />

and Slovakia have all introduced private enforcement.<br />

And in many common law countries—Australia, Canada,<br />

New Zealand, Uganda—the creditor’s attorney is responsible<br />

for enforcement, with the help of the police.<br />

Better incentives for remuneration—as when the enforcer<br />

is paid a percentage of the recovered claim, or<br />

a nominal fee plus a pro-rated bonus—speed up collection.<br />

22 These schemes are superior to a flat fee or wages<br />

(figure 8.7). Russia is a recent example of reform. In 2002,<br />

the remuneration rules for bailiffs were changed so that a<br />

bailiff would receive a bonus of 2% of the debt claim if he<br />

successfully collected the money. This change improved<br />

small debt recovery and had a lesser, but still positive, effect<br />

on collecting larger debts. The reason is that the<br />

bonus was capped at 800 rubles ($27), so the bailiff gets<br />

the same reward for all cases of 40,000 rubles or more. As<br />

larger amounts are more difficult to collect, enforcement<br />

focused on the easier cases. 23<br />

Finally, a reform that usually fails: increasing the<br />

number of judges to reduce court congestion. Such reform<br />

has obtained strong support in the development<br />

FIGURE 8.6<br />

Courts take longer to enforce a judgment<br />

Days between judgment and enforcement<br />

Court<br />

enforcement<br />

time<br />

Private or<br />

specialized<br />

public<br />

enforcement<br />

time<br />

Poor<br />

countries<br />

–15%<br />

Source: Doing <strong>Business</strong> database.<br />

Middle income<br />

countries<br />

–25%<br />

Rich<br />

countries<br />

–39%<br />

aid community. 24 This is understandable: by simple<br />

arithmetic, the more the judges, the fewer cases per<br />

judge. And it works for a brief period, after which delays<br />

increase again as more people bring cases to court, while<br />

the efficiency of dealing with each case remains the same.<br />

Sri Lanka is an example. To take the burden off the<br />

regular civil courts, specialized tribunals have been created<br />

to hear tax disputes, consumer complaints, and<br />

labor cases. But the civil courts remain as backlogged as<br />

ever. This is because the solution—more judges—treats<br />

the manifestation of the problem, not the problem itself.<br />

A simple rule for reformers: when the judiciary<br />

argues for more judges, it is time to also simplify procedures.<br />

It costs less and has longer term effects.<br />

Why reform?<br />

The fewer procedures, the lower the cost, the shorter the<br />

time to resolve disputes—the better that businesses rate<br />

the efficiency and integrity of the courts (figure 8.8) and<br />

the more likely that businesses are to go to the judge the<br />

next time a dispute arises. As confidence in dispute resolution<br />

rises, entrepreneurs become more willing to<br />

enter contracts beyond their narrow circle of known<br />

business partners. Trade increases and business expands,<br />

bring-ing more prosperity. A survey of Russian<br />

entrepreneurs shows that twice as many entrepreneurs<br />

start business in cities like Taganrog, where the courts<br />

are perceived as efficient, as in cities like Rostov-on-<br />

Don, where courts are perceived as corrupt and slow. 25<br />

A study comparing the corporate sectors in Mexico<br />

and the United States finds that weaknesses in contract<br />

FIGURE 8.7<br />

Payment incentives for enforcers cut time<br />

Days between judgment and enforcement<br />

Enforcer<br />

paid fixed fee<br />

Enforcer paid<br />

pro-rated fee<br />

178<br />

104<br />

Poor<br />

countries<br />

Source: Doing <strong>Business</strong> database.<br />

151<br />

82<br />

Middle income<br />

countries<br />

89<br />

29<br />

Rich<br />

countries

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!