28.08.2013 Views

The Future of Animal Agriculture in North America - Farm Foundation

The Future of Animal Agriculture in North America - Farm Foundation

The Future of Animal Agriculture in North America - Farm Foundation

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

eak the rules; discipl<strong>in</strong>e is far more difficult to impose <strong>in</strong> a<br />

collective approach. For a voluntary, collective approach to be<br />

effective, some elements <strong>of</strong> the food <strong>in</strong>dustry must be will<strong>in</strong>g<br />

and able to impose sanctions <strong>in</strong> the event standards are not<br />

met. <strong>The</strong>re will also be costs for audits and enforcement. <strong>The</strong><br />

potential for enforcement exists <strong>in</strong> the FMI/NCCR program if<br />

food retailers and restaurant cha<strong>in</strong>s refuse to do bus<strong>in</strong>ess with<br />

non-conform<strong>in</strong>g suppliers. McDonald’s has been a leader <strong>in</strong> this<br />

approach. Food processors and <strong>in</strong>tegrators could play a similar<br />

role <strong>in</strong> help<strong>in</strong>g to ensure that agreed standards are met at the<br />

producer level. However, producers are the ones that will<br />

implement the animal welfare practices, make necessary<br />

<strong>in</strong>vestments and cover, at least <strong>in</strong>itially, any added costs. <strong>The</strong>y<br />

must also be <strong>in</strong>volved <strong>in</strong> develop<strong>in</strong>g the standards adopted.<br />

Economic Impacts<br />

Unless animal production practices actually result <strong>in</strong> lower<br />

productivity and efficiency <strong>in</strong> the animal <strong>in</strong>dustry or pose a<br />

threat to human health, low animal welfare standards do not<br />

impose an economic cost on society. In fact, society as a whole<br />

may ga<strong>in</strong> economically if the prices <strong>of</strong> animal products are<br />

lower due to current production practices.<br />

It is sometimes argued that animal welfare is a public good, i.e.,<br />

all members <strong>of</strong> society benefit from a system that treats animals<br />

<strong>in</strong> certa<strong>in</strong> ways, or, alternatively, that certa<strong>in</strong> production systems<br />

impose external costs on society that are not reflected <strong>in</strong> the<br />

price <strong>of</strong> animal products. In both cases, there will be a market<br />

failure—the wrong quantity <strong>of</strong> a desired attribute is supplied, <strong>in</strong><br />

this case welfare. <strong>The</strong> public as a whole may suffer “psychic<br />

costs” <strong>in</strong> the sense that the well-be<strong>in</strong>g <strong>of</strong> members <strong>of</strong> society is<br />

reduced by the knowledge that certa<strong>in</strong> practices are used <strong>in</strong> the<br />

search for lower cost food, but there is little evidence <strong>of</strong> true<br />

market failure (failure to account for economic costs) associated<br />

with animal welfare (Carlsson et al., 2003). Consequently, if a<br />

choice is made to impose higher welfare standards <strong>in</strong> farm<strong>in</strong>g, it<br />

must be based on criteria other than economics.<br />

Production Costs and Consumer Response<br />

More research is needed to understand the relationship between<br />

<strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g animal welfare standards and production costs. In<br />

some cases, higher welfare standards are likely to <strong>in</strong>crease<br />

production costs for animal products. Changes <strong>in</strong> conf<strong>in</strong>ement<br />

operations, particularly <strong>in</strong>creased space requirements, may<br />

create additional capital costs through the modification <strong>of</strong><br />

exist<strong>in</strong>g facilities or construction <strong>of</strong> new or larger facilities.<br />

Extensive production systems, such as free-range eggs, require<br />

more land. Operat<strong>in</strong>g costs may <strong>in</strong>crease due to greater use <strong>of</strong><br />

labor <strong>in</strong> car<strong>in</strong>g for animals, higher energy costs <strong>in</strong>volved <strong>in</strong><br />

runn<strong>in</strong>g larger facilities, and higher feed costs if feed<strong>in</strong>g<br />

efficiency decl<strong>in</strong>es because <strong>of</strong> greater energy use by unconf<strong>in</strong>ed<br />

animals. If production systems require fewer animals produc<strong>in</strong>g<br />

<strong>Animal</strong> Welfare 139<br />

less meat, milk or eggs <strong>in</strong> a given period, there will be less<br />

output per dollar <strong>of</strong> total costs. In this case, there will be less<br />

total production unless there are more production units built<br />

rais<strong>in</strong>g concerns about air quality, site selection and neighbor<br />

conflict, and, particularly for outdoor facilities, water quality<br />

related to manure run<strong>of</strong>f issues, as discussed <strong>in</strong> the<br />

Environmental Issues Chapter. Higher standards may also<br />

<strong>in</strong>crease the costs <strong>of</strong> transport<strong>in</strong>g and process<strong>in</strong>g animals.<br />

Multidiscipl<strong>in</strong>ary approaches are necessary <strong>in</strong> balanc<strong>in</strong>g various<br />

trade-<strong>of</strong>fs. Focus<strong>in</strong>g only on natural behaviors and ignor<strong>in</strong>g<br />

mortality (which is two times higher <strong>in</strong> non-cage systems) and<br />

disease issues are examples. Recent concerns about the spread <strong>of</strong><br />

H5N1 avian <strong>in</strong>fluenza by migratory birds have led to bans on<br />

outdoor poultry production <strong>in</strong> some European countries.<br />

Balanced aga<strong>in</strong>st this, there may be some cost sav<strong>in</strong>gs as a result<br />

<strong>of</strong> the application <strong>of</strong> higher welfare standards. Morbidity and<br />

mortality may decl<strong>in</strong>e and expenditures on disease control and<br />

treatment may decrease if animal health improves, though this<br />

may not necessarily be the case. Increases <strong>in</strong> reproductive<br />

efficiency may lead to cost sav<strong>in</strong>gs. For example, product<br />

quality may improve meat quality as a result <strong>of</strong> less stress <strong>in</strong> the<br />

handl<strong>in</strong>g and slaughter <strong>of</strong> animals.<br />

For example, total house feed efficiency favored hous<strong>in</strong>g birds<br />

at 48 square <strong>in</strong>ches. However, provid<strong>in</strong>g space to the new<br />

standards <strong>of</strong> 69 square <strong>in</strong>ches <strong>in</strong>creases per-hen productivity<br />

and lowers mortality (Bell et al., 2004). This is an example<br />

where economics and welfare are not <strong>in</strong> opposition.<br />

<strong>The</strong> net effect on costs <strong>of</strong> changes <strong>in</strong> standards is difficult to<br />

determ<strong>in</strong>e. Some changes that reduce the stress imposed on<br />

animals <strong>in</strong> handl<strong>in</strong>g can be relatively <strong>in</strong>expensive.<br />

Unfortunately, there have been relatively few studies <strong>of</strong> changes<br />

<strong>in</strong> production costs associated with changes <strong>in</strong> animal welfare<br />

standards. One analysis <strong>of</strong> <strong>in</strong>creases <strong>in</strong> poultry production costs<br />

associated with higher welfare standards <strong>in</strong> the EU estimates<br />

unit cost <strong>in</strong>creases rang<strong>in</strong>g from 5 percent for modest changes<br />

<strong>in</strong> practices for broilers and layers to 50 percent for more<br />

radical changes, such as free-range egg production (Table 1,<br />

Moynagh, 2000). Another study <strong>in</strong>dicates there is a major<br />

<strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> labor costs <strong>in</strong> switch<strong>in</strong>g from the use <strong>of</strong> cages to<br />

free-range production—roughly five times as much labor is<br />

required per bird, egg production per bird falls by 15 percent<br />

and the amount <strong>of</strong> feed used <strong>in</strong>creases by roughly 7 percent<br />

(Vocke, 1991).<br />

A recent study <strong>of</strong> the switch from traditional cage systems to<br />

alternative systems <strong>in</strong> the EU provides data that confirm some<br />

<strong>of</strong> these conclusions (Agra CEAS, 2004). <strong>The</strong> amount <strong>of</strong> feed<br />

used per kilogram <strong>of</strong> eggs is significantly higher <strong>in</strong> free-range<br />

and organic systems, compared to traditional cages (Table 2).<br />

<strong>The</strong>se alternatives also require more labor. Birds kept under

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!