20.10.2014 Views

Chapter 2. Progress towards the EFA goals - Unesco

Chapter 2. Progress towards the EFA goals - Unesco

Chapter 2. Progress towards the EFA goals - Unesco

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

0<br />

1<br />

0<br />

CHAPTER 2<br />

2<br />

Education for All Global Monitoring Report<br />

Specific<br />

programmes<br />

targeting highly<br />

marginalized<br />

groups are likely<br />

to have higher<br />

average costs<br />

55. Classroom<br />

construction costs include<br />

additional infrastructure<br />

required for an effective<br />

learning environment,<br />

such as furniture, latrines<br />

and water supply. Unit<br />

costs are based on an<br />

average of low- and<br />

high-cost construction<br />

scenarios in Theunynck<br />

(2009). Unit costs for<br />

lower secondary are<br />

assumed to be 25%<br />

higher.<br />

56. The regional average<br />

also corresponds to<br />

average salary targets in<br />

national education plans<br />

for sub-Saharan Africa<br />

(Bennell, 2009a).<br />

57. For <strong>the</strong> low-income<br />

countries included in <strong>the</strong><br />

costing exercise that are<br />

not in sub-Saharan Africa,<br />

average teacher salaries<br />

are <strong>2.</strong>5 times GDP per<br />

capita in primary school<br />

and 3.0 times in<br />

secondary.<br />

58. The costs of reaching<br />

<strong>the</strong> marginalized are<br />

excluded when non-salary<br />

spending as a proportion<br />

of total recurrent cost<br />

is calculated.<br />

59. The wide range<br />

of policy interventions<br />

needed to address<br />

marginalization are<br />

explored in detail in<br />

<strong>Chapter</strong> 3.<br />

For example, lowering teacher salaries may<br />

cut costs but lead to low morale, making it more<br />

difficult to recruit a workforce with sufficient skills<br />

and forcing teachers to supplement <strong>the</strong>ir pay<br />

with o<strong>the</strong>r work.<br />

Capital cost estimates raise ano<strong>the</strong>r set of<br />

difficulties. By definition, achieving Education<br />

for All requires school infrastructure that is<br />

accessible to all children and of sufficient quality<br />

to ensure safety and provide an appropriate<br />

learning environment. Costs of classroom<br />

construction vary enormously. Reasonablepractice<br />

standards point to a cost of about<br />

US$13,500 per classroom, rising to US$17,000<br />

for lower secondary school. 55 Classrooms<br />

obviously need to be built to accommodate<br />

children currently out of school. But <strong>the</strong><br />

dilapidated state of <strong>the</strong> school infrastructure in<br />

many countries means <strong>the</strong>re is also a need for<br />

extensive investment in rehabilitation. One<br />

recent survey suggests that 30% of classrooms<br />

in low-income sub-Saharan Africa need replacing<br />

(Theunynck, 2009). Conflict-affected countries<br />

face particularly pressing problems. To take<br />

one example, half of Liberia’s classrooms were<br />

destroyed or sustained major damage during<br />

<strong>the</strong> civil war (Liberia Ministry of Education, 2007b).<br />

The parameters set for this Report’s costing<br />

exercise are derived from international evidence<br />

on norms and current practice in key areas.<br />

They include <strong>the</strong> following:<br />

Teacher salaries. Individual countries have to<br />

address issues of efficiency, norms and standards<br />

for teachers in <strong>the</strong> light of national circumstances.<br />

The costing exercise does not prejudge <strong>the</strong><br />

appropriate teacher salary level. Instead, it takes<br />

<strong>the</strong> current regional average for primary and lower<br />

secondary salaries in sub-Saharan Africa as a longterm<br />

target that all countries in <strong>the</strong> region will<br />

converge on. 56 For countries outside sub-Saharan<br />

Africa, <strong>the</strong> benchmark is lower (see Table <strong>2.</strong>9). 57<br />

Rules and norms. While <strong>the</strong>re is some debate about<br />

optimal pupil/teacher ratios, here <strong>the</strong> bar is set at<br />

40:1 for primary school, reflecting <strong>the</strong> target used in<br />

previous costing exercises. Effective teaching also<br />

requires access to stationery, textbooks and o<strong>the</strong>r<br />

learning equipment. Ensuring that one-third of <strong>the</strong><br />

recurrent budget is directed <strong>towards</strong> non-salary<br />

costs (rising to 40% for lower secondary education)<br />

should enable most low-income countries to meet<br />

basic needs in this respect. 58<br />

Wider capital costs. As well as covering <strong>the</strong> cost<br />

of future enrolment, budgets have to absorb <strong>the</strong><br />

cost of replenishing infrastructure. A conservative<br />

estimate is that about a quarter of <strong>the</strong> classrooms<br />

in low-income countries need replacing, rising<br />

to half in conflict-affected countries. As with<br />

<strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r targets, it is assumed that all this<br />

replacement takes place by 2015.<br />

Cost of adult literacy programmes. In line with<br />

previous studies, <strong>the</strong> unit cost of adult literacy<br />

programmes is estimated at 8.9% of GDP per<br />

capita for countries in sub-Saharan Africa and<br />

5.3% for all o<strong>the</strong>r countries (Van Ravens and<br />

Aggio, 2005, 2007).<br />

Reaching <strong>the</strong> marginalized<br />

Previous global cost estimates for education<br />

have assumed that <strong>the</strong> average cost of reaching<br />

out-of-school children is roughly equivalent to<br />

a national average benchmark. That assumption<br />

is misplaced. Specific programmes targeting highly<br />

marginalized groups including child labourers,<br />

<strong>the</strong> extreme poor, ethnic minorities, girls, children<br />

with disabilities, and locations such as remote<br />

rural areas and slums have to be financed.<br />

Moreover, extending education programmes<br />

to <strong>the</strong>se groups and areas is likely to raise per<br />

capita spending requirements.<br />

Top-down estimates are a particularly blunt tool<br />

for assessing <strong>the</strong> financing required to reach <strong>the</strong><br />

marginalized. Policy-makers need to consider <strong>the</strong><br />

interlocking constraints that keep marginalized<br />

children out of school or that disrupt <strong>the</strong>ir<br />

participation and limit <strong>the</strong>ir learning achievements<br />

(see <strong>Chapter</strong> 3). Detailed poverty assessments<br />

and planning processes that draw on <strong>the</strong> evidence<br />

and perspectives provided by <strong>the</strong> marginalized<br />

<strong>the</strong>mselves are critical to policy design.<br />

With this caveat in mind, international evidence<br />

yields some useful insights. Cash transfer<br />

programmes that provide social protection can<br />

play an important role in insulating vulnerable<br />

households from external shocks, enabling <strong>the</strong>m<br />

to keep children in school. In some contexts, such<br />

programmes have played a particularly crucial<br />

role in allowing girls to enter and stay in school.<br />

Under <strong>the</strong> right circumstances, school feeding<br />

programmes can also provide strong incentives<br />

for children to attend school (as well as crucial<br />

health benefits). Effective programmes of this<br />

kind typically cost about 5% of GDP per capita<br />

(Bundy et al., 2009a; Fiszbein et al., 2009a) 59 .<br />

124

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!