04.06.2013 Views

The Devil and Commodity Fetishism in South America - autonomous ...

The Devil and Commodity Fetishism in South America - autonomous ...

The Devil and Commodity Fetishism in South America - autonomous ...

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

<strong>Devil</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>Commodity</strong> <strong>Fetishism</strong> 25<br />

tions to the <strong>in</strong>ner significance of capitalist organization. To underst<strong>and</strong><br />

this reaction it is helpful to analyze the salient differences between<br />

the use-value system that underlies peasant economics <strong>and</strong><br />

the market basis of capitalism. Above all it is necessary to underst<strong>and</strong><br />

the way <strong>in</strong> which the market system of modern capitalism engenders<br />

a market<strong>in</strong>g mentality <strong>in</strong> which people tend to be seen as<br />

commodities <strong>and</strong> commodities tend to be seen as animated entities<br />

that can dom<strong>in</strong>ate persons. This socially <strong>in</strong>stituted paradox arises<br />

because, unlike earlier forms of organization which jo<strong>in</strong>ed persons<br />

<strong>in</strong>to direct relationships for production <strong>and</strong> exchange (often predicated<br />

on their control over the means of production), the market <strong>in</strong>terposes<br />

itself between persons, mediat<strong>in</strong>g direct awareness of social<br />

relations by the abstract laws of relationships between commodities.<br />

<strong>The</strong> peasant mode of production differs from the capitalist mode<br />

<strong>in</strong> fundamental ways. Under capitalism the proletariat work force<br />

lacks the control over the means of production that peasants exercise.<br />

<strong>The</strong> peasant uses cash, not capital, <strong>and</strong> sells <strong>in</strong> order to buy,<br />

whereas the capitalist uses cash as capital to buy <strong>in</strong> order to sell at a<br />

profit, thus add<strong>in</strong>g to capital <strong>and</strong> repeat<strong>in</strong>g the circuit on an ever-<strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g<br />

scale lest the enterprise die. <strong>The</strong> peasant producer lives <strong>in</strong> a<br />

system that is aimed at the satisfaction of an array of qualitatively<br />

def<strong>in</strong>ed needs; contrarily, the capitalist <strong>and</strong> the capitalist system<br />

have the aim of limitless capital accumulation.<br />

In the realization of this aim, capitalism stamps its products <strong>and</strong><br />

its means of production with the seal of market approval—price.<br />

Only by "translat<strong>in</strong>g" all the varied qualities that constitute its<br />

products <strong>and</strong> means for creat<strong>in</strong>g them <strong>in</strong>to one common "language,"<br />

that of currency, can the generator of capitalism's vitality, the market,<br />

operate. Known as "commodities," goods <strong>and</strong> services under<br />

capitalism thus differ enormously from their counterparts <strong>in</strong> precapitalist<br />

systems of livelihood. Although they may <strong>in</strong> fact be the<br />

same articles, socially <strong>and</strong> conceptually they are very different. To<br />

take Aristotle's famous example, a shoe is a shoe, physically,<br />

whether it is produced for wear or for sale at a profit with the aim of<br />

accumulat<strong>in</strong>g capital. But as a commodity the shoe has properties<br />

that are <strong>in</strong> addition to its use-value of provid<strong>in</strong>g comfort, ease of<br />

walk<strong>in</strong>g, pleasure to the eye, or whatever. As a commodity the shoe<br />

has the exchange-value function: it can generate profit for its owner<br />

<strong>and</strong> seller over <strong>and</strong> above the use-value that it holds for the person<br />

who eventually buys <strong>and</strong> wears it. In its exchange-value the shoe is<br />

qualitatively identical with any other commodity, no matter how<br />

much they may differ <strong>in</strong> terms of their use-value properties—their

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!