23.01.2014 Views

Reverse-Share-Tenancy and Marshallian Inefficiency - International ...

Reverse-Share-Tenancy and Marshallian Inefficiency - International ...

Reverse-Share-Tenancy and Marshallian Inefficiency - International ...

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

3. THEORETICAL MODEL<br />

Starting from the reverse share tenancy scenario <strong>and</strong> the inherent tenure insecurity in the Ethiopian tenure<br />

system, we draw on a two-period utility maximization model developed by Kassie <strong>and</strong> Holden (2007,<br />

2008) to show how the threat of eviction by the l<strong>and</strong>lord upon unsatisfactory performance increases the<br />

performance or incentives of an agent to work hard in the first period <strong>and</strong> thereby reduces the <strong>Marshallian</strong><br />

disincentive effects on the output of sharecropped l<strong>and</strong>.<br />

We assume that the tenant is risk averse <strong>and</strong> maximizes expected utility (U) of income (Y) from<br />

farm production (Q) from Peasant Association (PA) allocated l<strong>and</strong> (A o ) <strong>and</strong> leased l<strong>and</strong> (A r ) with the<br />

probability ( η)<br />

of carrying the rental contract through period two to produce Q r2 . We assume that the<br />

probability of contract renewal ( η)<br />

in period two depends on the amount of output produced in period<br />

one (Q r1 ) <strong>and</strong> on kinship relations between the l<strong>and</strong>lord <strong>and</strong> the tenant, measured by ( κ)<br />

. In addition, we<br />

assume that the economic <strong>and</strong> tenure security of the l<strong>and</strong>lord (S) is a critical factor affecting the<br />

probability of contract renewal. 5 Hence, the probability of contract renewal is given by<br />

2<br />

r1<br />

η = η( Q , κ, S), <strong>and</strong><br />

∂η r1 > 0,<br />

∂η > 0,<br />

∂η < 0,<br />

∂ η<br />

r1<br />

> 0<br />

∂Q ∂κ<br />

∂S<br />

∂Q ∂S<br />

. (1)<br />

Thus, we assume that good performance is more important to reduce the threat of eviction<br />

(probability of contract renewal) when tenants deal with l<strong>and</strong>lords with higher tenure security <strong>and</strong> strong<br />

socioeconomic status, which ultimately decrease the search costs <strong>and</strong> thereby the cost of eviction of the<br />

tenant. We assume eviction threats could be harder to impose by l<strong>and</strong>lords with weak bargaining power<br />

<strong>and</strong> insecure property rights conditions due to their poor bargaining position <strong>and</strong> economic dependence.<br />

When l<strong>and</strong>lords enjoy tenure security <strong>and</strong> stronger economic conditions (better bargaining power), the<br />

threat of eviction upon unsatisfactory performance is real <strong>and</strong> high, forcing tenants to cultivate the leased<br />

l<strong>and</strong> with greater care <strong>and</strong> intensity. In contrast, when l<strong>and</strong>lords are economically dependent <strong>and</strong> tenure<br />

insecure, this may undermine their power of eviction, in which case the <strong>Marshallian</strong> disincentive effects<br />

are visible (Kassie <strong>and</strong> Holden 2007, 2008).<br />

Following Kassie <strong>and</strong> Holden (2007) a two-period utility maximization model for a<br />

sharecropping owner-cum-tenant is developed <strong>and</strong> given by<br />

o1<br />

⎧ pq 1θ<br />

1Q ( Ao 1, xo 1, zo 1, zh 1)<br />

px 1x<br />

⎫<br />

⎪⎣<br />

⎡<br />

−<br />

o1⎦ ⎤<br />

⎪<br />

Max EU(Y) = EU1<br />

⎨ ⎬<br />

A<br />

1<br />

it , xit<br />

, z<br />

r<br />

it<br />

⎪ ⎡pq 1θ1Q ( Ar1, xr1, zr1, zh 1)<br />

β px 1x<br />

⎤<br />

⎩<br />

+ ⎣<br />

−<br />

r1⎦⎪⎭<br />

⎧<br />

⎪<br />

⎡<br />

⎣η( Q (.), κ, S). p θ Q ( A , x , z , z ) β − p x<br />

+ ρEU2<br />

⎨<br />

o2<br />

⎪+ ⎡pq2θ<br />

2Q ( Ao2,<br />

xo2, zo2, zh2)<br />

px2x<br />

⎤<br />

⎩ ⎣<br />

−<br />

o2⎦<br />

r1 r2<br />

q2 2 r2 r2 r2 h2 x2 r2<br />

, (2)<br />

where β is the output share going to the tenant in a pure sharecropping arrangement; the subscripts o =<br />

PA-allocated plots, r = leased plot, <strong>and</strong> 1 <strong>and</strong> 2 indicate period one <strong>and</strong> two, respectively; ρ is the<br />

1<br />

discount factor given by , <strong>and</strong> δ is the discount rate; x is conventional inputs (fertilizer, labor,<br />

1+<br />

δ<br />

⎤⎫<br />

⎦⎪<br />

⎬<br />

⎪⎭<br />

5 Bezabih <strong>and</strong> Holden (2012) shows that female l<strong>and</strong>lords who are assumed to have a poor socioeconomic <strong>and</strong> property<br />

rights status are less likely to exercise their power of eviction due to high search costs <strong>and</strong> insecurity of l<strong>and</strong> ownership. In our<br />

study, gender, the income-generating ability of the l<strong>and</strong>lord, whether or not the l<strong>and</strong>lord is a pure or cultivating l<strong>and</strong>lord, <strong>and</strong><br />

possession of a l<strong>and</strong> use certificate by the l<strong>and</strong>lord household are the four key variables used as indicators to capture the<br />

economic <strong>and</strong> tenure security parameter (S).<br />

5

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!