29.10.2012 Views

Abuse of Economic Dependence - The Centre for European Policy ...

Abuse of Economic Dependence - The Centre for European Policy ...

Abuse of Economic Dependence - The Centre for European Policy ...

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

How to Rectify the Gap 93<br />

Depending on whether the product <strong>of</strong> the non-dominant undertaking is<br />

homogeneous or differentiated, the impact on consumers will vary since<br />

their ability to find alternative sources <strong>of</strong> supply will vary.<br />

• Lack <strong>of</strong> objective justification.<br />

Where an undertaking has been found to have infringed Article 82, the<br />

undertaking can defend its conduct by arguing that it is ‘objectively justified’.<br />

Should the undertaking succeed in this defence, the conduct will not<br />

amount to an abuse. 45 This concept, developed by the ECJ and the<br />

Commission, distinguishes abusive conduct from that which is pursued<br />

as a matter <strong>of</strong> legitimate commercial policy. However, this defence<br />

cannot apply to conduct whose aim is to weaken competition. In addition,<br />

it involves an element <strong>of</strong> proportionality. 46<br />

A dynamic, rather than static, analysis <strong>of</strong> the market structure will allow<br />

the Commission to per<strong>for</strong>m an accurate assessment <strong>of</strong> the anti-competitive<br />

conduct <strong>of</strong> non-dominant firms. Such a dynamic analysis will incorporate a<br />

number <strong>of</strong> other structural factors beyond market shares and market<br />

concentration that can affect the degree <strong>of</strong> intra-market rivalry in a market.<br />

Such dynamic analysis would entail the assessment <strong>of</strong> the extent <strong>of</strong> intramarket<br />

rivalry which will depend on whether firms’ cost structures are very<br />

similar or not, and how low-cost firms utilize this advantage. In addition<br />

the degree <strong>of</strong> spare capacity in a market and the ease with which existing<br />

capacity can be expanded are two additional factors that may influence the<br />

degree <strong>of</strong> intra-market rivalry. Furthermore, the ownership and organizational<br />

<strong>for</strong>m <strong>of</strong> firms might also affect the degree <strong>of</strong> intra-market rivalry.<br />

and assess the extent to which such a negative effect on consumers is potentially outweighed<br />

by efficiency gains. <strong>The</strong> identification <strong>of</strong> competitive harm requires spelling out a consistent<br />

business behaviour based on sound economics and supported by facts and empirical evidence.<br />

Similarly, efficiencies and how they are passed on to consumers should be properly justified on<br />

the basis <strong>of</strong> economic analysis and grounded on the facts <strong>of</strong> each case.’<br />

45 Rousseva (2006) argues that the scope <strong>of</strong> objective justification is not entirely clear but it<br />

has generally been accepted that the objective justification refers to public policy concerns or<br />

other objective factors, such as crisis in the industry, which <strong>for</strong>ce undertakings to deviate from<br />

their normal course <strong>of</strong> conduct. She conducts an analysis <strong>of</strong> important precedents and adds<br />

that Community Courts understand the concept <strong>of</strong> objective justification to include only two<br />

types <strong>of</strong> considerations: (i) purely objective factors beyond the control <strong>of</strong> undertakings (not<br />

only dominant ones) which prevent those undertakings from carrying out their normal course<br />

<strong>of</strong> conduct; and (ii) public policy considerations which are generally <strong>of</strong> a non-economic nature<br />

but in particular circumstances, <strong>for</strong> example where there is a need to provide efficient service<br />

to the public, may be given an economic dimension. See further: Rousseva E, ‘<strong>The</strong> Concept <strong>of</strong><br />

‘Objective Justification’ <strong>of</strong> an <strong>Abuse</strong> <strong>of</strong> a Dominant Position: Can it help to Modernise the<br />

Analysis under Article 82 EC?’ [2005] 2(2) Comp L Rev.<br />

46 C Stothers (2001) ‘Refusal to Supply as <strong>Abuse</strong> <strong>of</strong> a Dominant Position: Essential Facilities<br />

in the <strong>European</strong> Union’ [2001] 7 ECLR 256, 260.

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!