18.05.2014 Views

The economic effects of EU-reforms in corporate income tax systems

The economic effects of EU-reforms in corporate income tax systems

The economic effects of EU-reforms in corporate income tax systems

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

2 <strong>The</strong> CORTAX model<br />

This study adopts two different tools <strong>in</strong> analys<strong>in</strong>g <strong>corporate</strong> <strong>tax</strong> <strong>reforms</strong>. <strong>The</strong> CORTAX model<br />

is a computable general equilibrium model for the <strong>EU</strong>, describ<strong>in</strong>g the macro-<strong>economic</strong><br />

implications <strong>of</strong> the <strong>reforms</strong>. <strong>The</strong> ORBIS database conta<strong>in</strong>s micro <strong>in</strong>formation from European<br />

firms, which is used for the calibration <strong>of</strong> CORTAX and for the design <strong>of</strong> <strong>tax</strong> <strong>reforms</strong>. This<br />

section discusses the features <strong>of</strong> CORTAX and demonstrates how ORBIS is used <strong>in</strong> its<br />

calibration. Appendix A <strong>of</strong>fers some technical details.<br />

2.1 Structure <strong>of</strong> CORTAX<br />

CORTAX is an applied general equilibrium model that describes the 27 countries <strong>of</strong> the<br />

European Union, plus the US and Japan. It is designed to simulate the <strong>economic</strong> implications <strong>of</strong><br />

unilateral and multilateral <strong>corporate</strong> <strong>tax</strong> policies as well as the harmonisation <strong>of</strong> these policies.<br />

<strong>The</strong> model is heavily <strong>in</strong>spired by the OECDTAX-model <strong>of</strong> Sørensen (2001; 2004ab; 2007). An<br />

earlier version <strong>of</strong> CORTAX was used for European <strong>tax</strong> policy analysis <strong>in</strong> Bettendorf et al.<br />

(2006, 2007) and Van der Horst et al. (2007). A detailed description <strong>of</strong> the structure and<br />

parameterisation <strong>of</strong> the model can be found <strong>in</strong> Bettendorf and van der Horst (2008).<br />

<strong>The</strong> structure <strong>of</strong> each country is the same. Countries are l<strong>in</strong>ked to each other via trade <strong>in</strong><br />

goods markets, <strong>in</strong>ternational capital markets and mult<strong>in</strong>ational firms. Below, we discuss the<br />

model structure <strong>of</strong> each country <strong>in</strong> more detail as well as the <strong>in</strong>ternational l<strong>in</strong>kages.<br />

2.1.1 Households<br />

Follow<strong>in</strong>g the overlapp<strong>in</strong>g generations model <strong>of</strong> Diamond, households are assumed to live for<br />

two periods. One may <strong>in</strong>terpret one period to cover 40 years. We express all variables <strong>in</strong> annual<br />

terms to facilitate the <strong>in</strong>terpretation <strong>of</strong> the outcomes <strong>in</strong> terms <strong>of</strong> national accounts data.<br />

Behaviour with<strong>in</strong> each 40-year period is assumed to be constant.<br />

Households make their decisions regard<strong>in</strong>g work, consumption and sav<strong>in</strong>g by maximiz<strong>in</strong>g a<br />

life-time utility function subject to an <strong>in</strong>tertemporal budget constra<strong>in</strong>t. When young (i.e. the first<br />

period), households choose to allocate their time between leisure and work. When old (i.e. the<br />

second period) household do not work but only consume. Young households receive after-<strong>tax</strong><br />

wage <strong>in</strong>come and lump-sum transfers. This <strong>in</strong>come at a young age is allocated over<br />

consumption and sav<strong>in</strong>gs. Sav<strong>in</strong>gs are <strong>in</strong>vested <strong>in</strong> a mix <strong>of</strong> bonds and stocks, which are<br />

assumed to be imperfect substitutes and which yield different rates <strong>of</strong> return. In the second<br />

period, households are retired. Consumption at old age is f<strong>in</strong>anced by the assets saved from the<br />

first period plus an after-<strong>tax</strong> rate <strong>of</strong> return and by lump-sum transfers. Moreover, the older<br />

generation is assumed to own the fixed factor used by firms. <strong>The</strong>refore, the old receive the<br />

<strong>economic</strong> rents.<br />

6

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!