22.03.2015 Views

Interim Report - TEEB

Interim Report - TEEB

Interim Report - TEEB

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

Box 3.5: Putting it together – an example of a<br />

Cost of Policy Inaction study on biodiversity loss<br />

In November 2007, a consortium 1 started work on a<br />

“Cost of Policy Inaction” or COPI study (Braat, ten<br />

Brink et al. 2008) on the costs of not halting<br />

biodiversity loss. COPI’s approach is the mirror<br />

image of benefits valuation, with the use of scenario<br />

analysis. Their terms of reference were to build up a<br />

global quantitative picture between now and 2050,<br />

and to try to value this in monetary terms.<br />

The project succeeded in establishing an appropriate<br />

approach (see diagram), identifying the data gaps<br />

and the methodological problems, and providing<br />

indicative figures. Some interesting, be they only<br />

illustrative, results have been produced.<br />

MODELLING BIODIVERSITY LOSS<br />

The GLOBIO model was used to project changes<br />

in terrestrial biodiversity to 2050 (OECD 2008). The<br />

main indicators were changes in land use and quality<br />

and the mean abundance of the original species of an<br />

ecosystem (MSA), for all of the world’s biomes. The<br />

model provides regional estimates for conversions<br />

from natural to managed forest and from extensive<br />

to intensive agriculture, and for the resulting decline<br />

in natural areas. The largest driver for conversions<br />

has historically been demand for agricultural land<br />

and timber, although infrastructure development,<br />

fragmentation, and climate change are predicted to<br />

become increasingly important. The expected loss of<br />

biodiversity by 2050 is about 10-15% (decline in MSA),<br />

the most extreme being in savannah and grassland.<br />

Figure 3.3: Establishing a scenario analysis<br />

OECD<br />

Baseline scenario<br />

International<br />

policies<br />

Change in<br />

land use,<br />

climate,<br />

pollution,<br />

water use<br />

Change in<br />

biodiversity<br />

Change in<br />

ecosystem<br />

services<br />

Change in<br />

economic<br />

value<br />

Change in<br />

ecosystem<br />

functions<br />

It is therefore important not to limit assessments to monetary<br />

values, but to include qualitative analysis and physical<br />

indicators as well. The “pyramid” diagram in Figure 3.2<br />

illustrates this important point.<br />

Measurement approaches vary depending on what we<br />

measure. For provisioning services (fuel, fibre, food, medicinal<br />

plants, etc.), measuring economic values is relatively<br />

straightforward, as these services are largely traded on<br />

markets. The market prices of commodities such as timber,<br />

agricultural crops or fish provide a tangible basis for<br />

economic valuation, even though they may be significantly<br />

distorted by externalities or government interventions and<br />

may require some adjustments when making international<br />

comparisons.<br />

For regulating and cultural services, which generally do not<br />

have any market price (with exceptions such as carbon<br />

sequestration) economic valuation is more difficult. However,<br />

a set of techniques has been used for decades to estimate<br />

non-market values of environmental goods, based either on<br />

some market information that is indirectly related to the<br />

service (revealed preference methods) or on simulated<br />

markets (stated preference methods). These techniques have<br />

been applied convincingly to many components of<br />

biodiversity and ecosystem services (an overview of the<br />

34 The economics of ecosystems and biodiversity

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!