22.03.2015 Views

Interim Report - TEEB

Interim Report - TEEB

Interim Report - TEEB

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

The scenario used was largely developed by the<br />

OECD as its baseline (OECD 2008). It is broadly<br />

consistent with other modelling exercises such as<br />

those by the FAO or other UN agencies. The model<br />

itself forecasts a slowing rate of biodiversity loss in<br />

Europe (compared to an increasing rate worldwide).<br />

ASSESSING CHANGES IN ECOSYSTEM<br />

SERVICES AND APPLYING MONETARY VALUES<br />

Changes in land use and biodiversity are translated<br />

into changes in ecosystem services. The assessment<br />

relies to a large extent on the valuation<br />

literature, and creative solutions have been developed<br />

to extrapolate and fill data gaps. This is an area<br />

where further work is clearly needed in Phase II.<br />

The biggest difficulty has been to find studies to<br />

monetize changes in ecosystem services. While<br />

there are many case studies, not all regions, ecosystems<br />

and services are equally covered, and there<br />

were often difficulties in identifying values per<br />

hectare for use in such a widespread benefit transfer.<br />

Also, most studies are based on marginal losses,<br />

and the values are often location specific.<br />

THE VALUATION RESULTS<br />

In the first years of the period 2000 to 2050, it is<br />

estimated that each year we are losing ecosystem<br />

services with a value equivalent to around EUR 50<br />

billion from land-based ecosystems alone (it has to<br />

be noted that this is a welfare loss, not a GDP loss,<br />

as a large part of these benefits is currently not<br />

included in GDP). Losses of our natural capital<br />

stock are felt not only in the year of the loss, but<br />

continue over time, and are added to by losses<br />

in subsequent years of more biodiversity. These<br />

cumulative welfare losses could be equivalent to<br />

7% of annual consumption by 2050. This is a<br />

conservative estimate, because:<br />

• it is partial, excluding numerous known loss<br />

categories, for example all marine biodiversity,<br />

deserts, the Arctic and Antarctic; some ecosystem<br />

services are excluded as well (disease<br />

regulation, pollination, ornamental services,<br />

etc.), while others are barely represented (e.g.<br />

erosion control), or under-represented (e.g.<br />

tourism); losses from invasive alien species are<br />

also excluded;<br />

• estimates for the rate of land-use change and<br />

biodiversity loss are globally quite conservative;<br />

• the negative feedback effects of biodiversity and<br />

ecosystem loss on GDP growth are not fully<br />

accounted for in the model;<br />

• values do not account for non-linearities and<br />

threshold effects in ecosystem functioning.<br />

CONCLUSIONS AND NEXT STEPS<br />

The study showed that the problem is potentially<br />

severe and economically significant, but that we<br />

know relatively little both ecologically and economically<br />

about the impacts of future biodiversity<br />

loss. Further work is envisaged in Phase II to<br />

address the points mentioned above, and further<br />

elaborate on the framework and methodology in<br />

line with our recommendations.<br />

1. The Cost of Policy Inaction (COPI): The case of not meeting the 2010<br />

biodiversity target (ENV.G.1/ETU/2007/0044) was carried out by a<br />

consortium led by Alterra, together with the Institute for European<br />

Environmental Policy (IEEP) and further consisting of Ecologic, FEEM, GHK,<br />

NEAA/MNP, UNEP-WCMC and Witteveen & Bos.<br />

suitability of these methods to valuate ecosystem services is<br />

provided by the Millennium Ecosystem Assessment (2005b).<br />

But they remain controversial.<br />

Fundamentally, there is the ethical question about the extent<br />

to which some life-supporting functions of biodiversity can<br />

be fully addressed by economic valuation and be considered<br />

as part of possible trade-offs instead of being dealt with as<br />

ecological constraints. Similarly, economic valuation may not<br />

be appropriate to address spiritual values. Keeping these<br />

limitations in mind, substantial progress has been made since<br />

the 1990s by economists working with natural scientists to<br />

improve these methods: there is increasing consensus on<br />

the conditions under which they can be used, and increasing<br />

confidence in the comparability of the results. These<br />

techniques are now commonly applied to measure a wide<br />

range of values, including many indirect and non-use values.<br />

Another set of challenges relates to assessing the consequences<br />

of the loss of biodiversity and ecosystem services<br />

on a large scale. First, valuation methods generally do not<br />

cover second-round effects of the losses on the wider<br />

economy. To assess such effects, the use of economic<br />

models is necessary. While there are already some promising<br />

Towards a valuation framework<br />

35

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!