08.02.2013 Views

entire book - Chris Hables Gray

entire book - Chris Hables Gray

entire book - Chris Hables Gray

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

[ 78 ] The Present<br />

tions of decision science and the "rational man" popularized by Herbert<br />

Simon. The connections between the rational man of economics, the<br />

artificial man of AI research, the pure scientist, and the perfect soldier are<br />

numerous. All these creatures share a common heritage. At their core are<br />

the same metarules of individuality, rationality, masculinity, and domination.<br />

All of them are supposed to rely on logic, not emotion, for solving their<br />

problems. Relying on the "intellectual technologies" of systems analysis,<br />

management science, and related techniques to measure the costs versus<br />

benefits or economic expected utility, decision scientists claim they have<br />

created "a social-scientific approach to decision making." Have some knowledge<br />

engineers put it all into a machine and you have an expert system.<br />

In her analysis of Simon's work, Carolyn Miller (1990) reveals how it is<br />

focused on the metaphor of rationality in both economics and AI. Economic<br />

expected utility, complexified to multiattribute analysis and rational decision<br />

making, is now called problem solving. This has been Simon's focus for fifty<br />

years, although he conflates it to "The nature of human reason...." Miller<br />

goes on to show how Simon's idea of rationality is "instrumentalist," in that<br />

Simon has replaced "Olympian Rationality" (omniscient and absolute) with<br />

procedural rationality. She calls this "scientistic" and contrasts it to her idea<br />

of reasonable rationality, that is, "the discovery and articulation of good<br />

reasons for belief and action." So, in Miller's terms, history, convention,<br />

insight, emotion, and value all become rational, that is, possible "good<br />

reasons" for thinking or doing something.<br />

History? Insight? Emotion? Value? These elements are difficult to formalize,<br />

to put it mildly. Unsurprisingly, vulgar rationality remains dominant<br />

in many guises in many related discourses: the short-term rationality of our<br />

politico-military affairs with its roots in economic metaphors of material gain<br />

and loss (Chomsky, 1986) and the limited rationality of the bureaucracy, the<br />

computer, the man-on-the-street.<br />

Which isn't you or me. He is the computer model of the average<br />

consumer, voter, soldier, investor, or enemy; he is the rational man of<br />

economics, the "rational opponent" Henry Kissinger calls him. Kissinger<br />

defines him as someone who "must respond to his self-interest in a manner<br />

which is predictable" (quoted in Falk, 1987, p. 16). Being predictable by<br />

Henry Kissinger is rational? Some feminist philosophers have argued it is only<br />

a limited type of rationality, and it is predicated on relationships of domination.<br />

To show some of these relationships clearly and with their deeper<br />

structure, it will help to look at the critique of the role of limited versions of<br />

rationality in science that comes specifically from Carolyn Merchant and<br />

Sandra Harding.<br />

Merchant (1982) draws convincing lines between limited conceptions<br />

of rationality that are central to science and an attitude and practice toward<br />

nature of domination, dismemberment, even destruction. Given the con-

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!