02.02.2014 Views

pdf: 6.426kb - University of South Africa

pdf: 6.426kb - University of South Africa

pdf: 6.426kb - University of South Africa

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

war has made state and nation building almost<br />

impossible. Post-independent Angola continues to<br />

experience the absence <strong>of</strong> robust democratic means<br />

<strong>of</strong> venting disenchantment with government policies<br />

and measures. In such a situation <strong>of</strong> political failure,<br />

the MPLA state depends on power, war and resource<br />

capture to secure its undemocratic grip over society ±<br />

all variables incorporated into the triangular model. As<br />

mentioned before, the state did not hesitate to recruit<br />

aid in the form <strong>of</strong> private mercenary armies to marginalize<br />

the opposition. The problem is that military<br />

solutions are generally short-term, invariably abusive<br />

<strong>of</strong> human rights and inevitably fail to heal the underlying<br />

causes <strong>of</strong> state failure (Messiant 1998:151±153;<br />

New <strong>Africa</strong>n Yearbook 1999:26; Global Witness 1998;<br />

Mail and Guardian 12 May 1999:1).<br />

It suffices to say that the sustained ability <strong>of</strong> FARC,<br />

ELN and UNITA to act as `de facto' rival government<br />

in sizeable areas under their control also contributes to<br />

the state's security failure. In the case <strong>of</strong> Colombia,<br />

FARC and the ELN control and administer nearly half<br />

<strong>of</strong> the territory; organize their own local elections;<br />

patrol roads and waterways; collect taxes, and hold<br />

trials <strong>of</strong> suspected criminals. Their counterpart, UNI-<br />

TA, cannot boast <strong>of</strong> the same magnitude <strong>of</strong> power and<br />

control (Sweeney 1999:3).<br />

Socio-economic failure<br />

Angola and Colombia's socio-economic failure experiences<br />

have different origins. In Angola, the MPLA<br />

government initially favoured the classical Soviet<br />

model <strong>of</strong> development, imposing radical collectivization<br />

and state-controlled industrialization with little<br />

room for gradualism. About 65 per cent <strong>of</strong> GDP were<br />

controlled by the state between 1976 and 1985. In the<br />

country, Angolans were cut <strong>of</strong>f arbitrarily from their<br />

traditional tribal structures and beliefs. Instead <strong>of</strong><br />

uniting all segments <strong>of</strong> socio-economic society, the<br />

state alienated large sub-ethnic tribes and the farming<br />

community through its centralized development policy.<br />

The latter began to adjudge the MPLA in the same<br />

light as their Portuguese predecessors, while many<br />

considered UNITA as the new `liberator'. The prolonged<br />

civil war that followed made socio-economic<br />

failure and collapse inevitable, disrupting state structures<br />

responsible for food and other aid disbursement,<br />

and forcing thousands <strong>of</strong> people from their agricultural<br />

land. Production suffered in every sector, with<br />

agriculture, the livelihood <strong>of</strong> most Angolans, the<br />

hardest hit. Agricultural sector collapse did also have<br />

dire consequences for the nutrition and health status<br />

<strong>of</strong> the population, worsened by severe rural income<br />

decline. Instead <strong>of</strong> producing food surpluses, people<br />

have been forced into subsistence farming with little<br />

or no export capacity. Central government could no<br />

longer adequately facilitate and secure the availability<br />

<strong>of</strong> consumer goods. A dynamic private sector was<br />

almost non-existent.<br />

With increased poverty and infrastructural destruction,<br />

the state was no longer able to secure domestic<br />

taxation income, thus creating greater dependency on<br />

the Soviet bloc for its economic survival. The `minivortex'<br />

created by state failure during the Cold War era<br />

developed into a full blown war, due to increased<br />

Soviet and Cuban political, economic and military<br />

influence in Angola. Fear <strong>of</strong> communism in the US and<br />

<strong>South</strong> <strong>Africa</strong> was followed by increasingly destructive<br />

overt and covert military support and backing <strong>of</strong><br />

UNITA. However, superpower withdrawal following<br />

the end <strong>of</strong> the Cold War, did not bring an end to the<br />

long-term degenerating process <strong>of</strong> socio-economic<br />

failure in Angola. Instead, the protracted civil war and<br />

its socio-economic destruction continuing, new `nonideological'<br />

state (and nonstate actor) survival strategies<br />

merely saw an increased shift towards resource<br />

capture, control and exploitation, allowing them to<br />

`hang on'. For most Angolans, the weak MPLA state<br />

and government has been no better at generating<br />

resources and stabilizing allocation for sustained<br />

socio-economic development than was its predecessor<br />

± so it relies even more on control and coercion. In<br />

the absence <strong>of</strong> strong and dynamic government<br />

institutions and the physical infrastructure in a state<br />

<strong>of</strong> disarray, recent trade liberalization policies have<br />

been unable to generate socio-economic reconstruction<br />

beyond the oil production sector. Furthermore,<br />

foreign revenues from this sector have been selectively<br />

mis-allocated to exclusively benefit e lite groups.<br />

Socio-economic failure has also given rise to a<br />

situation where the informal economy tends to take<br />

over, overshadowing the formal economy in its<br />

transactions and escaping the control <strong>of</strong> the state<br />

(Messiant 1998:151; Zartman 1995:8±9; Fituni 1995).<br />

Angola, and to a lesser extent Colombia's economic<br />

failure can be attributed to their inability to benefit<br />

from enhanced market opportunities created by global<br />

trade liberalization, stimulating a demand for exports.<br />

On the one hand, as primary commodity exporters<br />

both countries have experienced mixed fortunes.<br />

While the recovery <strong>of</strong> crude oil prices resulted in a<br />

large surge in the value <strong>of</strong> exports (crude oil and<br />

petroleum products are among Angola and Colombia's<br />

main export commodities), the same could not<br />

be said <strong>of</strong> the agricultural commodity sector (e.g.<br />

cassava, bananas, c<strong>of</strong>fee, cotton, sugarcane). Colombia,<br />

for example, is the world's second-largest c<strong>of</strong>fee<br />

producer, after Brazil. Growth in world market<br />

demand for agricultural commodities has lagged<br />

behind that <strong>of</strong> value-added industrial goods, while<br />

industrialized countries have continuously boosted<br />

their own supply capacity through the application <strong>of</strong><br />

new technology. To protect their domestic markets,<br />

industrialized countries have also resorted to restrictive<br />

trade measures such as quotas and tariffs. The<br />

result: downward pressure on, for example, c<strong>of</strong>fee and<br />

cotton prices, as well as limited market accessibility.<br />

ISSN 0256±6060±Unisa Lat. Am. Rep. 16(2) 2000 21

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!