13.08.2013 Views

Asset Pricing John H. Cochrane June 12, 2000

Asset Pricing John H. Cochrane June 12, 2000

Asset Pricing John H. Cochrane June 12, 2000

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

SECTION 3.2 RISK NEUTRAL PROBABILITIES<br />

I denote the price p(x) to emphasize that it is the price of the payoff x. Where the payoff<br />

in question is clear, I suppress the (x). I like to think of equation (3.48) as a happy-meal<br />

theorem: the price of a happy meal (in a frictionless market) should be the same as the price<br />

of one hamburger, one small fries, one small drink and the toy.<br />

It is easier to take expectations rather than sum over states. To this end, multiply and<br />

divide the bundling equation (3.48) by probabilities,<br />

p(x) = X<br />

µ <br />

pc(s)<br />

π(s) x(s)<br />

π(s)<br />

s<br />

where π(s) is the probability that state s occurs. Then define m as the ratio of contingent<br />

claim price to probability<br />

m(s) = pc(s)<br />

π(s) .<br />

Now we can write the bundling equation as an expectation,<br />

p = X<br />

π(s)m(s)x(s) =E(mx).<br />

s<br />

Thus, in a complete market, the stochastic discount factor m in p = E(mx) exists, and it<br />

is just a set of contingent claims prices, scaled by probabilities. As a result of this interpretation,<br />

the combination of discount factor and probability is sometimes called a state-price<br />

density.<br />

The multiplication and division by probabilities seems very artificial in this finite-state<br />

context. In general, we posit states of nature ω that can take continuous (uncountably infinite)<br />

values in a space Ω. In this case, the sums become integrals, and we have to use some measure<br />

to integrate over Ω. Thus, scaling contingent claims prices by some probability-like object is<br />

unavoidable.<br />

3.2 Risk neutral probabilities<br />

I interpret the discount factor m as a transformation to risk-neutral probabilities such that<br />

p = E ∗ (x)/R f .<br />

Another common transformation of p = E(mx) results in “risk-neutral” probabilities.<br />

Define<br />

π ∗ (s) ≡ R f m(s)π(s) =R f pc(s)<br />

55

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!