13.08.2013 Views

Asset Pricing John H. Cochrane June 12, 2000

Asset Pricing John H. Cochrane June 12, 2000

Asset Pricing John H. Cochrane June 12, 2000

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

CHAPTER 4 THE DISCOUNT FACTOR<br />

negative, negating the assumption of no-arbitrage. ¤<br />

The tough part comes if markets are incomplete. There are now many m’s that price<br />

assets. Any m of the form m = x ∗ + ², with E(²x) =0will do. We want to show that at<br />

least one of these is positive. But that one may not be x ∗ . Since the discount factors other<br />

than x ∗ are not in the payoff space X, we can’t use the construction of the last argument,<br />

since that construction may yield a payoff that is not in X, and hence to which we don’t<br />

know how to assign a price. To handle this case, I adopt a different strategy of proof. (This<br />

strategy is due to Ross 1978. Duffie 1992 has a more formal textbook treatment.) The basic<br />

idea is another “to every plane there is a perpendicular line” argument, but applied to a space<br />

that includes prices and payoffs together. As you can see, the price = 0 plane is a separating<br />

hyperplane between the positive orthant and the negative payoffs, and the proof builds on this<br />

idea.<br />

Theorem: No arbitrage implies the existence of a strictly positive discount factor,<br />

m>0,p= E(mx) ∀ x ∈ X.<br />

Proof : Join (−p(x),x) together to form vectors in R S+1 . Call M the set of all<br />

(−p(x), x) pairs,<br />

M = {(−p(x),x); x ∈ X}<br />

M is still a linear space: m1 ∈ M, m2 ∈ M ⇒ am1 + bm2 ∈ M. No-arbitrage<br />

meansthatelementsofM can’t have all positive elements. If x is positive, −p(x)<br />

must be negative. Thus, M is a hyperplane that only intersects the positive orthant<br />

R S+1<br />

+ at the point 0. We can then create a linear function F : RS+1 ⇒ R such that<br />

F (−p, x) =0for (−p, x) ∈ M, andF (−p, x) > 0 for (−p, x) ∈ R S+1<br />

+ except<br />

the origin. Since we can represent any linear function by a perpendicular vector,<br />

there is a vector (1,m) such that F (−p, x) =(1,m) · (−p, x) =−p + m · x or<br />

−p + E(mx) using the second moment inner product. Finally, since F (−p, x) is<br />

positive for (−p, x) > 0,mmust be positive.<br />

¤<br />

In a larger space than R S+1<br />

+ , as generated by continuously valued random variables, the<br />

separating hyperplane theorem assures us that there is a linear function that separates the two<br />

convex sets M and the equivalent of R S+1<br />

+ , and the Riesz representation theorem tells us that<br />

we can represent F as an inner product with some vector by F (−p, x) =−p + m · x.<br />

What the theorem does and does not say<br />

The theorem says that a discount factor m>0 exists, but it does not say that m>0 is<br />

unique. The left hand panel of Figure <strong>12</strong> illustrates the situation. Any m on the line through<br />

x ∗ perpendicular to X also prices assets. Again, p = E[(m + ε)x] if E(εx) =0. All of<br />

these discount factors that lie in the positive orthant are positive, and thus satisfy the theorem.<br />

There are lots of them! In a complete market, m is unique, but not otherwise.<br />

72

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!