13.08.2013 Views

Asset Pricing John H. Cochrane June 12, 2000

Asset Pricing John H. Cochrane June 12, 2000

Asset Pricing John H. Cochrane June 12, 2000

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

SECTION 4.1 LAW OF ONE PRICE AND EXISTENCE OF A DISCOUNT FACTOR<br />

Furthermore, for any valid discount factor m,<br />

x ∗ = proj(m | X).<br />

So far we have derived the basic pricing relation p = E(mx) from environments with a<br />

lot of structure: either the consumption-based model or complete markets.<br />

Suppose we observe a set of prices p and payoffs x, and that markets — either the markets<br />

faced by investors or the markets under study in a particular application — are incomplete,<br />

meaning they do not span the entire set of contingencies. In what minimal set<br />

of circumstances does some discount factor exists which represents the observed prices by<br />

p = E(mx)? This section and the following answer this important question. This treatment<br />

is a simplified version of Hansen and Richard (1987), which contains rigorous proofs and<br />

some technical assumptions.<br />

Payoff space<br />

The payoff space X is the set (or a subset) of all the payoffs that investors can purchase,<br />

or it is a subset of the tradeable payoffs that is used in a particular study. For example, if there<br />

are complete contingent claims to S states of nature, then X = RS . But the whole point is<br />

that markets are (as in real life) incomplete, so we will generally think of X as a proper subset<br />

of complete markets RS .<br />

The payoff space will include some set of primitive assets, but investors can also form<br />

new payoffs by forming portfolios. I assume that investors can form any portfolio of traded<br />

assets:<br />

A1: (Portfolio formation) x1,x2 ∈ X ⇒ ax1 + bx2 ∈ X for any real a, b.<br />

Of course, X = RS for complete markets satisfies the portfolio formation assumption. If<br />

there is a single basic payoff x, then the payoff space must be at least the ray from the origin<br />

through x. If there are two basic payoffs in R3 , then the payoff space X must include the<br />

plane defined by these two payoffs and the origin. Figure 8 illustrates these possibilities.<br />

The payoff space is not the space of returns. The return space is a subset of the payoff<br />

space; if a return R is in the payoff space, then you can pay a price $2 to get a payoff 2R,so<br />

the payoff 2R with price 2 is also in the payoff space. Also, −R is in the payoff space.<br />

Free portfolio formation is in fact an important and restrictive simplifying assumption. It<br />

rules out short sales constraints, bid/ask spreads, leverage limitations and so on. The theory<br />

can be modified to incorporate these frictions, but it is a substantial modification.<br />

If investors can form portfolios of a vector of basic payoffs x (say, the returns on the<br />

NYSE stocks), then the payoff space consists of all portfolios or linear combinations of these<br />

original payoffs X = {c0x} where c is a vector of portfolio weights. We also can allow truly<br />

infinite-dimensional payoff spaces. For example, investors might be able to trade nonlinear<br />

65

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!