25.10.2014 Views

jp8589 WRI.qxd - World Resources Institute

jp8589 WRI.qxd - World Resources Institute

jp8589 WRI.qxd - World Resources Institute

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

Namibian conservancies, for example, revenues from tourist<br />

access, campgrounds, and the sale of game hunting licenses to<br />

foreigners generate income that in some instances has been<br />

turned into a cash payout to each conservancy household—an<br />

easy way to assure equal treatment (US AID 2004:13).<br />

But in other instances, easy division may be impossible. For<br />

example, in many restored watersheds the increase in water will<br />

not result in accumulation of surface water in ponds where shares<br />

can be calculated. Instead, extra water may manifest as more<br />

groundwater, which is legally the property of the land owner from<br />

whose well it is pumped to the surface. This makes the community<br />

benefit difficult to calculate and hard to tap by poor families<br />

without land or wells. Addressing this would require an arrangement<br />

where groundwater is considered community property no<br />

matter where it is pumped, with users paying a fee to the community<br />

to tap it (Kerr 2002a:1391-1392, 1399).<br />

Another approach to community equity is to grant special<br />

arrangements just to the lowest income families. For example,<br />

one Indian village in Maharashtra state granted to the village’s<br />

landless residents exclusive fishing rights in a run-off pond that<br />

the community had built (Kerr 2002a:1391-1392, 1399).<br />

Likewise, low-income families could be allowed special areas to<br />

fish, extra harvest or grazing periods, or an extra share of the<br />

resource being managed. In all cases, this requires a progressive<br />

view of benefits and a careful definition of user rights that is<br />

formalized and accepted by the community.<br />

Acknowledging the Limits of Participation<br />

There is a growing consensus that communities can establish<br />

functioning institutions capable of managing local resources,<br />

and that these institutions—from village councils to user<br />

groups—can function through community participation, making<br />

real the promise of local devolution. But there is also the realization<br />

that community processes are rarely egalitarian. Except in<br />

rare instances, communities are not homogeneous, and naturally<br />

break into various interest groups, making equity a challenge.<br />

Often, these are based along class, ethnic, and gender lines, with<br />

women and the poor usually being the least powerful of these<br />

groups (Kellert et al. 2000:705; Shyamsundar et al. 2004:16-17,<br />

19; Kerr 2002a:1388-1389; Kumar 2002:765-766).<br />

A scene several years ago from a village meeting about a<br />

new watershed restoration project in the Indian state of<br />

Karnataka illustrates the problem. At the front of the room sat<br />

the wealthiest landholders, who owned fertile, irrigated land in<br />

the valley bottom. Behind them sat middle-income farmers with<br />

less-desirable but still good land. In the back stood poor families<br />

with the least fertile land at the top of the watershed. The<br />

landless hung around the periphery; no women were present<br />

(Fernandez 2003:6-7).<br />

In situations such as these, assuring true participation for<br />

the poor requires considerable institution-building so that<br />

mechanisms of inclusion can gradually work against ingrained<br />

social patterns. For example, one NGO in Maharashtra state<br />

that helps villages undertake watershed restoration programs<br />

insists on a consensus-based approach to all decisions about the<br />

watershed and spends a good deal of time facilitating such<br />

decisions and building the social basis necessary to foster them<br />

(Kerr et al. 2002:16, 34). Although it is more unwieldy than a<br />

majority vote, this approach offers an organic way to make sure<br />

the interests of the landless minority are not simply swept aside.<br />

91

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!