23.02.2016 Views

ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT

YFksc

YFksc

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

goals of the government in their area of responsibility, and an ability to operate<br />

in a political environment” (1986).<br />

Moreover, although CEA’s strength is providing unvarnished economic<br />

advice, it is impossible to divorce this advice from the broader<br />

context of the Administration’s goals and objectives. While economists can<br />

help policymakers to weigh tradeoffs among different policy options or to<br />

design policies so that they are more likely to achieve their stated objective,<br />

how those tradeoffs are weighed and goals are set often depends on values.<br />

In addition, policy recommendations themselves are more relevant if they<br />

can be implemented, which in turn depends on a range of political factors<br />

like legislative feasibility and how the policy is described and contextualized.<br />

Finally, CEA chairs are selected and agree to serve because they at least<br />

broadly share the goals and values of the President and the administration.<br />

Beyond the chair, however, there is no guarantee that CEA members, or<br />

especially staff economists and researchers, share a political or philosophical<br />

agreement with the President.<br />

As dictated in the Employment Act of 1946, CEA’s advice must ultimately<br />

be guided by its own analysis of which economic policies will foster<br />

and promote free competitive enterprise, avoid economic fluctuations, and<br />

maintain employment, production, and purchasing power. Former CEA<br />

chairs, members, and staff offer several specific pieces of advice as to how<br />

to successfully strike this balance: they advise that CEA should not publicly<br />

advocate for policies that are not supported by economic analysis, and that<br />

CEA should stick to giving economic advice, not political advice. CEA’s<br />

comparative advantage is economics, and as illustrated by Keyserling’s<br />

tenure and its aftermath, straying outside this function risks damaging the<br />

institution’s credibility.<br />

Others advise that the Council should not get too involved in policy<br />

coordination. CEA’s limited staff and resources, combined with the academic<br />

background of most of its staff, render it poorly equipped to serve as<br />

a policy coordinating body. One episode that illustrates this lesson occurred<br />

during the Johnson Administration, when CEA was responsible for the<br />

day-to-day administration of wage-price guideposts to combat inflation.<br />

Reflecting on the experience, Walter Heller remarked that there was no<br />

other appropriate agency to handle the wage-price guideposts, but that it<br />

was “diversionary” and that “the Council has to stay away from that kind of<br />

operational responsibility” (Hargrove and Morley 1984).<br />

Excessive involvement in policy coordination can also have the effect<br />

of undermining CEA’s institutional credibility, due to the types of compromises<br />

that are necessary. Hugh Norton writes that CEA’s efforts to administer<br />

the wage-price guidelines “had the effect of weakening the general moral<br />

The 70th Anniversary of the Council of Economic Advisers | 317

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!