12.02.2018 Views

Holt 7525-9 S15_IT

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

Ideally, the burden imposed by a tax would be no greater than the funding provided to the<br />

government. Quoting from “The Wealth of Nations” by Adam Smith, “Every tax ought to be so<br />

contrived as both to take out and to keep out of the pockets of the people as little as possible,<br />

over and above what it brings into the treasury of the state…” Realistically, a tax will impose a<br />

burden on the taxpayers larger than the funding provided to the government. This is called<br />

excess burden.<br />

Excess burden – the amount that the burden imposed by a tax exceeds the funding provided by<br />

the tax.<br />

Example 7: The government wants to provide $100 million to fund a new government program. If<br />

a tax is imposed which provides the government with $100 million for the new program and<br />

imposes a burden on the taxpayers of only $100 million, there will be no excess burden.<br />

Any tax is likely to impose excess burden. Some taxes will impose a very large excess burden. A<br />

good (economically efficient) tax is one which imposes as little excess burden as possible.<br />

The sources of excess burden include:<br />

1. The cost for the government to collect the tax. The government will incur costs to<br />

administer and enforce a tax. To minimize the collection cost of a tax, the tax should be as<br />

simple as possible. A general sales tax is an example of a simple tax which is relatively cheap<br />

for the government to collect, while the federal personal income tax is an example of a<br />

complex tax.<br />

Example 8: The government wants to provide $100 million to fund a new government program.<br />

If it costs the government $5 million to collect the tax, it will be necessary to collect $105 million<br />

from the taxpayers in order to fund the program. Thus, there is an excess burden of $5 million.<br />

2. The cost for the taxpayers to comply with the tax. Taxpayers will have to keep certain<br />

records, fill out forms, etc. to comply with a tax. To minimize the compliance cost of a tax, the<br />

tax should be as simple as possible. A general sales tax is an example of a simple tax which is<br />

relatively cheap for the taxpayers to comply with, while the federal personal income tax is an<br />

example of a complex tax.<br />

Example 9: The government wants to provide $100 million to fund a new government program. If<br />

the taxpayers spend thousands of hours keeping the necessary records and filling out the<br />

necessary forms to comply with the tax (or if the taxpayers pay experts to keep the records and<br />

fill out the forms), there will be a compliance cost imposed on the taxpayers. This adds to the tax<br />

burden without adding to the government’s funding, and is thus an excess burden.<br />

3. The deadweight loss of the tax. We saw in Chapter 3 that private market equilibrium is<br />

generally efficient, equalizing marginal benefit and marginal cost, and maximizing the net<br />

benefit of having the market available (the sum of consumer’s surplus and producer’s surplus).<br />

A tax may distort the decisions made in the private market. When a tax distorts the decisions<br />

made in the private market, the tax eliminates mutually beneficial transactions and thus<br />

reduces the net benefit of having the market available. This reduction is the deadweight loss of<br />

the tax.<br />

Example 10: The graphs on the next page represent the market for Good X from Example 12 in<br />

Chapter 3. The first graph shows the amount of consumer’s surplus and producer’s surplus<br />

before a tax is imposed. The sum of consumer’s surplus and producer’s surplus is the net benefit<br />

of having the market available. The market equilibrium is a price of $4 and a quantity of 15 units.<br />

The second graph shows the effect of a $2 per unit tax imposed on the sellers of Good X. The<br />

supply curve shifts vertically upward by the amount of the tax. The after-tax equilibrium is a price<br />

FOR REVIEW ONLY - NOT FOR DISTRIBUTION<br />

Taxes, Deficits, and the National Debt 13 - 4

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!