12.02.2018 Views

Holt 7525-9 S15_IT

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

Appendix: Book Review – “The Myth of the Rational Voter”<br />

In 2007, economist Bryan Caplan published “The Myth of the Rational Voter: Why Democracies<br />

Choose Bad Policies”. In this book, Caplan asserts that voters are not just rationally ignorant, but<br />

are systematically biased in favor of mistaken views.<br />

In theory, policies that are harmful to the best interest of society should not occur in a democracy.<br />

The majority of voters would not vote in favor of socially harmful policies, nor would they vote in<br />

favor of elected officials who enacted socially harmful policies. Yet socially harmful policies (e.g.<br />

trade restrictions) often do occur in democracies. Typically, these socially harmful policies have<br />

been blamed on rational voter ignorance and the influence of special-interest groups. But Caplan<br />

asserts that democracy delivers socially harmful policies because it gives the voters what they<br />

want. Voters are worse than ignorant. They are irrational. They embrace a number of economic<br />

misconceptions and thus consistently favor economic policies that are harmful to the best interest<br />

of society.<br />

Voter ignorance has been recognized for decades. It no longer shocks voter analysts that over<br />

half of Americans cannot name their congressional representative, or that voters believe that<br />

foreign aid consumes a much larger share of the federal budget than it actually does. But<br />

economists have assumed that voter ignorance is not necessarily harmful. It is assumed that<br />

voters will not make systematic errors, but rather random errors. The random errors of the<br />

uninformed voters will cancel each other out and the few informed voters will determine the<br />

outcome.<br />

Example 13: A vote is being held on an economic policy. Policy X is a good policy and Policy Y is<br />

a bad policy. Assume that 98% of voters are uninformed and 2% are well-informed. The<br />

uninformed voters are not biased toward one policy or the other and thus tend to vote randomly.<br />

Half of the uninformed voters vote for Policy X and half vote for Policy Y. Thus, each policy has<br />

received 49% of the total vote. Then the well-informed voters vote. They will all vote in favor of<br />

the good policy (Policy X). Thus, the good policy will win by a 51% to 49% majority. And the fact<br />

that 98% of the voters were uninformed has done no harm.<br />

But what if the majority of voters are not just uninformed, but are systematically biased in favor of<br />

mistaken views? Then the majority of voters may vote in favor of socially harmful policies and in<br />

favor of elected officials who enact socially harmful policies. This is precisely what happens,<br />

according to Caplan. According to Caplan, the vast majority of voters are noneconomists, and<br />

noneconomists are biased toward four common misconceptions:<br />

1. Antimarket bias. This is a tendency to underestimate the economic benefits of the market<br />

mechanism. Noneconomists fail to comprehend that profit-seeking businesses in a competitive<br />

market will generally produce socially beneficial outcomes. Economists recognize that the goal<br />

of profit-maximization causes firms to be responsive to consumer demand and to produce<br />

efficiently. Noneconomists tend to see profits as simply a transfer to the businesses and fail to<br />

see the beneficial incentives that profits provide. Noneconomists also fail to comprehend how<br />

market-determined prices efficiently allocate resources and goods. They tend to see monopoly<br />

and conspiracy behind price movements.<br />

2. Antiforeign bias. This is the tendency to underestimate the economic benefits of interaction<br />

with foreigners. Noneconomists usually can comprehend the mutual benefits of specialization<br />

and trade on a local or national level. But when the trade crosses national boundaries,<br />

noneconomists assume that trade is a zero-sum game. If Japan is benefiting by selling<br />

Toyotas to America, America must be losing.<br />

3. Make-work bias. This is the tendency to underestimate the economic benefits of conserving<br />

labor. Noneconomists tend to have mixed feelings about technological advances that destroy<br />

jobs and to absolutely oppose downsizing and outsourcing. Economists recognize that labor is<br />

a valuable limited resource and that society benefits from conserving labor. The misconception<br />

that job destruction is harmful rests on the idea that employment, not production, is the source<br />

of prosperity. (For more on job destruction and economic growth, see Chapter 4.)<br />

FOR REVIEW ONLY - NOT FOR DISTRIBUTION<br />

Public Choice and Government Failure 28 - 8

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!