01.05.2014 Views

Research 350 - NZ Transport Agency

Research 350 - NZ Transport Agency

Research 350 - NZ Transport Agency

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

2. APPROACHES TO ASSESSING NATIONAL ECONOMIC BENEFITS<br />

Responses<br />

There is little debate about the need to include environmental (and other) externalities in<br />

SCBA, though SACTRA has been somewhat ambivalent as to whether these are included<br />

‘above the line’ or below it. Recently released Australian <strong>Transport</strong> Council guidelines (ATC<br />

2004) recommend inclusion of externalities, while noting the difficulty of valuing the<br />

externalities in monetary terms. Austroads (2003a) provides unit values for environmental<br />

externalities for use in road projects calibrated to New Zealand and Australian conditions.<br />

The effect of including environmental impacts in SCBA can vary. In the case of a fixed trip<br />

matrix, it is likely that project benefits will increase due to environmental benefits associated<br />

with the improved transport conditions, albeit modest benefits commensurate with the lack<br />

of any effect on travel behaviour. The outcome would be different where travel demand<br />

changes as a result of a project, but is seems likely to reduce project benefits if travel<br />

demand rises.<br />

The inclusion of environmental externalities does not present an insurmountable issue for<br />

SCBAs and, in principle; they should be included within such an assessment. However,<br />

notwithstanding the Austroads work, monetary values are not available for every appraisal<br />

context. Where this is the case, such externalities may be included ‘below the line’ as a<br />

qualitative (dis) benefit.<br />

Broader economic benefits<br />

It can be claimed that SCBA does not take account of some broader economic benefits,<br />

primarily because it is a partial equilibrium approach. This is addressed in the general sense<br />

in the next subsection. Consideration is then given to the nature of these benefits, which<br />

include: logistics benefits; agglomeration benefits; other positive externalities; taxation<br />

impacts; and regional impacts.<br />

2.5.2.1 SCBA as a partial equilibrium approach<br />

Issues<br />

A typical transport SCBA captures impacts from investment in transport by examining only<br />

the effects of a proposal on transport outcomes, which are typically reduced travel time,<br />

vehicle operating costs and accident costs. Critics of SCBA often characterise this ‘partial<br />

equilibrium’ approach, which assumes that the broader economy is ‘fixed’ (e.g. typically<br />

treating factors such as the prices of transport inputs as exogenous and valuing savings in<br />

inputs at observed market prices), as thus failing to take account of all of the effects of a<br />

proposal 6 .<br />

Such critics argue that the development of transport infrastructure can yield more extensive,<br />

follow-on or transmitted economic benefits throughout the economy that are not picked up in<br />

SCBA due to its assumptions about exogeneity. These additional benefits (or ‘positive<br />

externalities’) are argued to be above and beyond those accruing due to the passing through<br />

of benefits such as initial travel time savings and vehicle operating cost savings to producers<br />

and consumers. Two commonly cited positive externalities claimed to be ‘omitted’ by SCBA<br />

6 In fact there is some blurring between the ‘partial equilibrium’ approach offered by SCBA and the<br />

general equilibrium approach offered by economic models. This is an issue which is further explored<br />

below.<br />

27

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!