01.05.2014 Views

Research 350 - NZ Transport Agency

Research 350 - NZ Transport Agency

Research 350 - NZ Transport Agency

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

4. APPROACHES TO ASSESSING REGIONAL ECONOMIC AND OTHER DISTRIBUTIONAL EFFECTS<br />

SACTRA’s recommendation that I-O be used to help analyse impacts on regional economies<br />

(DfT 1999, para. 75).<br />

However, as is the case on a national level I-O impacts should be seen as complementary<br />

rather then supplementary to SCBA. That is, SCBA should form the basis of the regional<br />

analysis (with regard to the ringfencing issues noted above). The outputs of the I-O model<br />

(i.e. GDP/GSP, income and employment) could then provide an additional set of data of<br />

interest to policymakers. Further, the issues relating to multiplier estimation and model<br />

constraints should be made transparent in the analysis.<br />

4.3.3 CGE analysis<br />

In theory, CGE analysis offers a more comprehensive approach to the estimation of regional<br />

economic effects than I-O, given its allowance for the operational of at least some economic<br />

constraints.<br />

In practice, the construction of regional CGE models is extremely problematic. The main<br />

problem is that of obtaining appropriate data on a regional scale.<br />

In many cases, regional CGE models have been developed within national models. This can be<br />

done through a ‘bottom up’ or ‘top down’ approach.<br />

The bottom up approach is based on the integration of sub-national I-O tables in combination<br />

with parameter estimates for location choice equations. However, as noted above, the<br />

derivation of I-O tables is a process which is open to considerable question, while the<br />

estimation of location choice parameters is often conjectural (BTE 1999, pp. 137-138).<br />

The top down approach is rarely used and involves defining national industries which drive<br />

demand for local industries. However, as it assumes that the location of ‘national industries’<br />

is given, its utility for assessing transport investments is limited (BTE, pp. 136-137).<br />

As noted above, past work has indicated that CGE models will often converge on I-O solutions<br />

at the regional level. Thus considerations of parsimony weigh against use of CGE within a<br />

regional context. This is also the conclusion of Docwra and West, who note that the<br />

difficulties of parameterising a large number of coefficients and parameters in the absence of<br />

local data will more then offset the increased model sophistication, and that applying CGE to<br />

regional economics may not be ‘a very efficient use of resources’ (Docwra and West 1999, p.<br />

941). Likewise, despite their general support for CGE (as opposed to I-O) modelling, Dwyer,<br />

Forsyth and Spurr agree that CGE modelling, while feasible, is ‘costly and unwarranted’ at the<br />

‘local level’ 30 .<br />

It is therefore considered that CGE analysis does not offer a practical approach to the<br />

modelling of regional economic impacts of transport investment in most cases.<br />

4.3.4 Other approaches<br />

Some analysts have suggested broad guidelines for the assessment of regional economic<br />

effects, without necessarily relating these to a specific modelling approach. For example,<br />

30 Note however, that these authors see CGE modelling as having a role to play at the ‘State-wide’ level<br />

(Dwyer, Forsyth & Spurr 2004, pp.313-314). This raises the question of application within a New Zealand<br />

context. Since the authors comments seem to relate to Australia, it is likely that CGE analysis is better<br />

applied to areas with larger economies and populations than those of most New Zealand regions (i.e.<br />

Australian states).<br />

97

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!