01.05.2014 Views

Research 350 - NZ Transport Agency

Research 350 - NZ Transport Agency

Research 350 - NZ Transport Agency

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT BENEFITS OF TRANSPORT INVESTMENT<br />

inter-temporal dynamics, they are not optimal for assessing such impacts (Docwra &<br />

West 1999, p. 942).<br />

• The benefits of such models are assumed to spread across the economy. This may be<br />

inappropriate for many transport investments which are local in character and where<br />

benefits tend to be ‘lumpy’. For example highway improvements in Perth may have<br />

only small impacts per se in Brisbane (Kinhill Economics 1994, pp. 15-16). Likewise,<br />

ACG’s analysis indicates most of the benefits from the Wellington Regional Land<br />

<strong>Transport</strong> package will accrue to Wellington (ACG 2004, pp. 43-46). Of course in cases<br />

where an investment program is truly national in character a national approach may be<br />

entirely justified – e.g. New Zealand Passing Lanes Project (ACG 2004).<br />

• Correspondingly, if the focus of the SCBA is on predicting transport outcomes CGE<br />

modelling will be of little use, due to its coarse, broad brush approach (BTE 1999, p.<br />

104).<br />

Some further key issues covering the ‘relationship’ between CGE and SCBA in particular are<br />

discussed below.<br />

2.6.2.1 CGE and SCBA<br />

As is the case with I-O analysis (and unlike SCBA) CGE modelling output consists of<br />

macroeconomic variables (GDP, employment, taxes consumption, investment, exports and<br />

imports, industry output impacts). As already noted, these are measures of economic impact<br />

rather than of economic efficiency or welfare.<br />

In addition, like I-O analysis, CGE analysis excludes the impact of some ‘non-market’ factors<br />

not measured in National Accounts data such as non-work travel time savings (to the extent<br />

that these are incorporated into increased leisure time), some accident cost savings (lives lost<br />

and permanent disability avoided) and environmental externalities.<br />

Some attempts have been made in the past to reconcile CGE model outputs with those of<br />

SCBA. In some cases these have focused on using changes in consumption expenditure<br />

produced by CGE models as a proxy for changes in net social welfare. This is argued to be<br />

comparable to the net social welfare measures (i.e. project NPV) produced by SCBA. An<br />

associated argument is that such approaches pick up the benefits allegedly omitted by SCBA.<br />

However, even when this is done, past Australian experience does not indicate that CGE<br />

models will necessarily produce greater indicators of benefit than traditional SCBA.<br />

For example, ACG analysed the benefits and costs of CityLink, using both the MMRF model<br />

and more ‘traditional’ SCBA measures (ACG 1996) 13 .<br />

The SCBA results indicated welfare gains some 11% greater than those estimated by the<br />

MMRF, after an adjustment for lack of model dynamics, discussed below (ACG; BTE 1999, p.<br />

113). Conversely, this does not imply that SCBA overestimated the benefits of CityLink; as<br />

BTE note, modelling uncertainties (such as the lack of dynamics) makes it difficult to infer<br />

much about the direction of the difference (BTE 1999, p. 113).<br />

13 The measure of welfare gain from the MMRF results was the change in real private and public<br />

consumption expenditure over the project life.<br />

50

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!